Abstract
A common problem in water resource allocation is to design a stable and feasible mechanism of water sharing in critical scarcity conditions. The task becomes very challenging when the water demand exceeds the available water resources reserves. To address this pervasive allocation problem related to transboundary rivers, the bankruptcy method is used. The bankruptcy method distributes water among riparian states when their total demand exceeds the total available water. This paper describes a new methodology for the allocation of scarce water resources in a complex system using a stochastic game theory which is an extension of bankruptcy theory. The authors have also proposed ‘weighted bankruptcy’ approach that can be used under a stochastic setting. The weighted bankruptcy approach favors agents with ‘high agricultural productivity’. The bankruptcy rules have been applied in the water resource system in four critical scarcity scenarios. The available water is allocated under the simple and weighted bankruptcy rules. The results showed that under all four scenarios, the weighted bankruptcy rules favor the agents which have a high agricultural productivity. The stochastic bankruptcy approach under the simple and the weighted bankruptcy rules can provide important strategic information for better management and sustainable sharing of water resources.
INTRODUCTION
Management and allocation of water in scarce conditions is a common problem in water resource management (Kanakoudis 2002; Kanakoudis et al. 2016, 2017). This problem of water allocation can be analyzed using bankruptcy game (BG) technique, which is a branch of cooperative games theory (CGT) (Young 1994). The problem of bankruptcy arises when some agents have claims on the available goods or assets, but their total claim is greater than the total available assets. The assets must be divided among the claimants or agents in such a way that each claimant or agent might receive a non-negative amount that cannot be greater than its claim. There are numerous applications of bankruptcy problems which include different real-life problems and the bankruptcy approach has proved very useful for those problems. In the literature, several bankruptcy rules and their extensions have been introduced to solve the bankruptcy problem (O'Neill 1982; Auman & Maschler 1985; Herrero & Villar 2001; Thomson 2003).
Several political disputes have been caused throughout the world due to the non-equitable distribution of water resources, the increasing consumption of resources, and the scarcity of water resources (Homer-Dixon 1994). There is a total of 148 transboundary river basins that are shared among 148 countries (De Stefano et al. 2012). During the past 50 years, 43 political or military acts related to shared water resources have taken place around the world (Wolf 2007). Due to factors such as climate change, growing crop production, increasing populations, and soil degradation, freshwater has become a source of conflict among riparian states. Hence, one of the main challenges in transboundary river management concerns how we can allocate the limited and shared available water among riparian states when it is not sufficient to satisfy the claims of all riparian states. Therefore, ‘equitable’ and ‘reasonable’ water resource reallocation faces the question of which criteria and mechanisms should be considered for this ‘equitable’ and ‘reasonable’ reallocation (Mianabadi et al. 2012). A variety of climatic, socioeconomic, environmental, geographical, historical, and political factors and conditions can affect water resources and, consequently, different types of water conflicts (Delli Priscoli & Wolf 2009). In one category, there are two different approaches to addressing water conflicts: first, conflicts over international water resources (Yoffe et al. 2003) such as aquifers, lakes, and rivers that are shared between two or more countries; second, conflicts over internal water resources shared between states, provinces, cities, or different groups within a specific country (Toset et al. 2000). In another category, there are two different types of water conflicts: conflicts over the quality (Perry & Vanderklein 2009) and conflicts over the availability (Ping & Ping 2010) of water resources. These conflicts can have different degrees in terms of intensity and seriousness. The complexity of water conflicts calls for accurate investigations for such conflicts to be effectively resolved. Shared water can be a source of both cooperation and conflict among riparians. The main problem arises when the total demand of riparian countries or provinces is more than the total available water. In quantitative conflict resolution, the equitable allocation of water among riparians is a complex process at both the national and international scales (Jarkeh et al. 2016).
To manage conflicts and allocate resources, the bankruptcy method is widely used. This method is applicable when the total claims (C) exceed the total resources or assets (E). Bankruptcy theory has been applied to problems related to the allocation of resources. Grundel et al. (2013) used this method for multipurpose resource allocation situations. Ansink & Marchiori (2015) used it for water resource management. In addition, Beard (2011) provided a detailed review of the connection between river sharing and the bankruptcy literature. The frequent application of the bankruptcy method reveals that it is a popular tool for resolving conflicts and for achieving agreement on water resource allocation problems. Bankruptcy theory can be used in resource allocation and dispute resolution when the total available resources are less than the total demand or claims of riparian countries or provinces (Ansink & Marchiori 2015). Auman & Maschler (1985) and O'Neill (1982) introduced bankruptcy theory, and it was later studied by various researchers (O'Neill 1982; Hendrickx et al. 2005; Lorenzo-Freire et al. 2010; Thomson 2012; Alcalde et al. 2014). Bankruptcy theory has been used by several researchers for water allocation among riparian countries (Madani et al. 2014; Mianabadi & Sheikhmohammady 2014; Mianabadi et al. 2015; Li et al. 2018). Bozorg-Haddad et al. (2018) used bankruptcy theory for water allocation in Iran. Degefu et al. (2018) applied the cooperative game theory allocation by combining the Nash bargaining theory and bankruptcy games for the water allocation among Syria, Iraq, and Turkey. Water management using system dynamics modeling in semi-arid regions was done by Reza et al. (2017). Sedghamiz et al. (2018) used a game theory approach for conjunctive use optimization model based on virtual water concept.
A methodology for water allocation using the bankruptcy games is described in this paper for water resources under scarcity. A new methodology is also developed which considers the priorities in the allocation of water. This novelty is presented by the consideration of the user's priorities, which are settled by ‘high agricultural productivity’: the user with high agricultural productivity will be given preference in water allocation. First, the water distribution among the provinces of Pakistan is done under four different scenarios using the bankruptcy rules. Second, we apply an allocation procedure that includes claimants' priority by considering the agricultural productivity of the users.
BANKRUPTCY PROBLEM AND COOPERATIVE GAME THEORY
The bankruptcy methods are used in economics when the available asset (resource) is not sufficient to satisfy the claim of creditors (stakeholders). When total available resources are below the aggregate demand, the expected use of each user needs to be reduced by some amount, which can be calculated using different bankruptcy methods available in the literature (Curiel et al. 1987; Dagan & Volij 1993; Madani & Dinar 2011). The foundations of these bankruptcy models are set in the works of O'Neill (1982) and Auman & Maschler (1985). The links between the cooperative game theory (CGT) and bankruptcy games (BG) were consolidated by Curiel et al. (1987), in which they studied the class of division rules for bankruptcy as corresponding to a CGT approach to those problems.
In fact, CGT (Neummann & Morgenstern 1944; Young 1985) provides the necessary instruments to analyze allocation problems and to research a sharing mechanism which is considered efficient, just, and fair by users. A cooperative game can be seen as a kind of game where it is necessary to determine the fair allocation of ‘goods’ among different players (Lemaire 1984). The allocation can consider ‘positive’ or ‘negative’ goods according to a ‘benefit game’ or a ‘cost game’ solution for the users. In the first case, users collaborate with each other in order to obtain the biggest fair benefit; in the second case, users collaborate to share the smallest cost system (Young 1994).
Many allocation problems have been addressed in the literature using the CGT. Different research fields have been considered in the approaches including water resources (Deidda et al. 2009; Zucca 2011).
Synthetically, to define a cooperative game problem, the following definitions are needed:
N = (1, 2, …, n) is the set of players participating in the game
S ∈ N is a ‘coalition’, and for S = N we have the so-called ‘grand coalition’
v(i) represents the minimum cost or maximum benefit connected to the user i
v(S) is the minimum cost or maximum benefit linked to the coalition S
v(N) consequently, represents the cost or benefit associated with the grand coalition.
The discrete function given by the costs or benefits of every coalition is called the characteristic function and represents a key element of the cooperative game solution. An allocation is a vector [x1, x2, … xn], where xi is the amount of the good assigned to the ith player.
Regarding a benefit-sharing game, to obtain a fair solution, CGT exploits three fundamental principles (in the case of a cost game the inequality signs are the opposite).
The sharing of total available goods is ensured by statement (1); the incentives for the voluntary cooperation is ensured by statement (2) while statement (3) provides the consideration for equity. Conditions (2) and (3) become equivalent as condition (1) is ensured.
Two different definitions are given in CGT for the game problem solution. The first is given by the set of admissible solutions: the so-called ‘core’ that is the set of all allocations x ∈ RN, such that (1) and (2), or equivalently (3), hold for all S of N (Young & Okada 1982). The second type is given by a single allocation, which individuates only one solution, and this is more similar to the classic idea of the solution to a problem.
BANKRUPTCY RULES
As described above, the bankruptcy methods are used in economics when the available stock is not sufficient to satisfy the claim of the claimants or creditors. Based on this, the assumption can be made that the total water resources are not sufficient to satisfy the demand of the claimants, therefore, these rules of bankruptcy can be used for the fair allocation of water resources to satisfy all the beneficiaries (Kaveh Madani 2012). A large amount of literature on bankruptcy problems and related division rules is available. Here, we mention the papers by Gallastegui et al. (2002), O'Neill (1982), Ansink (2009), and Mianabadi et al. (2015). More studies related to the bankruptcy rules have already been discussed in the Introduction.
The set N of claimants is of the form {1, 2, …, n}. Each claimant i ∈ N advances one claim di on the estate E with E < Σi∈Ndi.
In Equation (4), xi represents the amount of the estate E assigned to the ith claimant.
In this situation, the solution to the bankruptcy problem and the related cooperative game is the same. Hereafter, we consider division rules reported by Branzei et al. (2008) considering a flow approach to bankruptcy problems: the proportional rule (PROP), the constrained equal award rule (CEA), the constrained equal loss rule (CEL), the Talmudic rule (TAL), and the Piniles rule (Pin) which are explained below.
Proportional rule (PRO):
2. Constrained equal award (CEA) rule:
CEA assigns each agent an equal share λ of E, except that no creditor receives more than his or her claim.
- 3.
Constrained equal losses (CEL) rule:
- 4.
The Talmud rule:
- 5.
Piniles' rule:
In the above bankruptcy rules, the ‘estate’ amount E to be divided is the available water for users; moreover, different priorities or rights of the claimants are also considered by using the riparians' agricultural productivity.
WEIGHTED BANKRUPTCY RULE: METHODOLOGY DEVELOPMENT
All the bankruptcy rules defined above will then be applied again considering the weighted water demands. The weighted water requests are considered as the claims of the agents or riparians. If any riparian or claimant receives a greater water allocation than its original request, the assignment will be equal to its original request and available surplus will be shared among the other users using the same rule.
SOLUTION FRAMEWORK
After defining the objective, the fundamental principles of water sharing as stated in Equations (1)–(3) are defined. The disagreement points as well as the amount of water available for consumption is then determined. The allocation of water among the riparians is then done using the bankruptcy rules. The procedure for water allocation problem under water bankruptcy using the bankruptcy rules is described in Figure 1.
When the demand and the available water in the river basin changes with time, the bankruptcy rules are applied again by updating the disagreement points and the water allocation is done again using the bankruptcy rules.
CURRENT WATER DISTRIBUTION MECHANISM IN PAKISTAN AND ITS SHORTCOMING
The Islamic Republic of Pakistan is home to the sixth largest population in the world. There are four administrative units in the country, or four provinces, namely, Punjab, Sindh, Baluchistan, and Khyber Pakhtunkhwa. Pakistan also consists of small areas of Gilgit-Baltistan and federally administered tribal areas. Arable land and water are the principal natural resources of Pakistan, and agriculture significantly contributes to the country's economy. It accounts for almost 19.8% of the country's gross domestic product (GDP) (Anwar & Bhatti 2017). Of the 27% of cultivated land in Pakistan, Punjab has the highest proportion (63%), followed by Sindh (18%), and the remainder is equally divided between the provinces of Baluchistan and Khyber Pakhtunkhwa (Delli Priscoli & Wolf 2009; Ahmad 2017).
The interprovincial water sharing of surface waters in Pakistan is currently governed by the Water Apportionment Accord of 1991. The main aim of the accord was to build trust among the provinces of Pakistan. Unfortunately, this accord does not adapt to changing conditions over time; hence, it can be considered ‘a glass that is half empty and half full’. The current water distributions among the provinces of Pakistan according to the Water Apportionment Accord are given in Table 1. The Indus River System Authority (IRSA) is responsible for the distribution of water among the provinces. The main shortcomings of the Water Apportionment Accord of 1991 are highlighted below.
Province . | Water share (km3) . | Balance supply sharesa in % . |
---|---|---|
Punjab | 69.03 | 37 |
Sindhb | 60.17 | 37 |
Baluchistan | 4.78 | 12 |
KPK | 7.13 | 14 |
Ungauged canalsc | 3.70 | |
Total | 144.87 | 100 |
Province . | Water share (km3) . | Balance supply sharesa in % . |
---|---|---|
Punjab | 69.03 | 37 |
Sindhb | 60.17 | 37 |
Baluchistan | 4.78 | 12 |
KPK | 7.13 | 14 |
Ungauged canalsc | 3.70 | |
Total | 144.87 | 100 |
aIncluding future storages and flood flows.
bIncluding already sanctioned urban and industrial uses for Karachi.
cUngauged civil canals above rim stations in KPK.
The average canal diversions in post-Tarbela periods have only been 127 km3, which is less than the accord's entitlements of 144.87 km3, as shown in Tables 1 and 2. This creates problems among the provinces of Pakistan when they have to share shortages as there is no defined mechanism to share the water shortages (Condon et al. 2014). Currently, the two small provinces, Baluchistan and Khyber Pakhtunkhwa (KPK) are exempted by the water shortages by an act of 2003. Thus, whenever the total volume falls, the deficiencies are shared by Sindh and Punjab (Condon et al. 2014). Thus, there is no proper mechanism of water distribution when the total volume falls short or when the demands of the provinces exceed the total available water. Also, Khyber Pakhtunkhwa (KPK) and Baluchistan have not yet developed their irrigation system properly, therefore, they always get more water than they can use.
Water requirements for various crops . | Punjab km3 . | Sindh km3 . | KPK km3 . | Baluchistan km3 . | Total km3 . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Wheat | 26.72 | 5.17 | 3.05 | 1.20 | 36.12 |
Rice | 17.66 | 3.97 | 0.41 | 2.10 | 24.16 |
Cotton | 14.29 | 2.97 | 0.00 | 0.20 | 17.46 |
Sugarcane | 8.07 | 2.72 | 0.88 | 0.01 | 11.68 |
Maize | 2.04 | 0.01 | 1.69 | 0.02 | 3.76 |
Barley | 0.10 | 0.04 | 0.10 | 0.04 | 0.28 |
Other crops | 40.62 | 15.20 | 2.14 | 5.85 | 63.80 |
All crops | 109.49 | 31.07 | 8.28 | 9.42 | 157.25 |
All crops after Sindh's requirement for environmental flows | 109.49 | 43.37 | 8.28 | 9.42 | 170.56 |
Water requirements for various crops . | Punjab km3 . | Sindh km3 . | KPK km3 . | Baluchistan km3 . | Total km3 . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Wheat | 26.72 | 5.17 | 3.05 | 1.20 | 36.12 |
Rice | 17.66 | 3.97 | 0.41 | 2.10 | 24.16 |
Cotton | 14.29 | 2.97 | 0.00 | 0.20 | 17.46 |
Sugarcane | 8.07 | 2.72 | 0.88 | 0.01 | 11.68 |
Maize | 2.04 | 0.01 | 1.69 | 0.02 | 3.76 |
Barley | 0.10 | 0.04 | 0.10 | 0.04 | 0.28 |
Other crops | 40.62 | 15.20 | 2.14 | 5.85 | 63.80 |
All crops | 109.49 | 31.07 | 8.28 | 9.42 | 157.25 |
All crops after Sindh's requirement for environmental flows | 109.49 | 43.37 | 8.28 | 9.42 | 170.56 |
Note: The requirements for Sindh include an additional 12.3 km3 as environmental flows.
Another serious problem in the Water Apportionment Accord is that the water allocations are fixed which creates a quantified entitlement. Fixed water allocations' mechanisms can lead to water allocations which are unacceptable for the provinces, especially in the uncertainty, droughts, and the stochastic nature of river flow. The Water Apportionment Accord between the provinces of Pakistan was signed almost 28 years ago. Since then, the water demands of the provinces have changed due to the increase in population and the irrigated area. Therefore, the gap between the water supply and water demand has increased considerably in Pakistan. Several features and attributes of the Indus River disputes are described in the following section.
Surface water diversions
As shown in Figure 2, the Indus River, which is composed of six major tributaries, namely, the Indus, Chenab, Jhelum, Ravi, Beas, and Sutlej tributaries, is a major source of water supply for Pakistan. The water of the Indus River is shared among all four provinces of Pakistan. River flows are mainly supplied by rainfall, snowmelt, glacier melt, and runoff. According to the Indus River System Authority, the median canal diversions from 1975 to 2013 were 125.61 km3 (Hassan 2016).
Agricultural water requirements for Pakistan
In this study, the water requirements (in feet) for various crops were taken from the Planning Commission Report whereas the cropped area was taken from the Agricultural Statistics of Pakistan.
As per the Agricultural Census of Pakistan, Punjab has the largest cultivated area among the four provinces of Pakistan which accounts for about 56.6%, followed by Sindh, KPK, and Baluchistan. According to this study, the agriculture water requirements for Pakistan are 157.25 km3 (excluding the environmental flows). The water required downstream of Kotri as environmental flows for the province of Sindh is 12.3 km3. The 1991 Water Accord between the provinces also recognized the need for a residual flow to the delta of 12.3 km3, but no formal policy or institutional mechanism has yet been adopted to make environmental water allocations. There is a clear need for such environmental allocations to be made, not only for a minimum residual flow, but also to provide a measure of flow variability that mimics the natural river regime (Archer et al. 2010). The total water requirement including the environmental flows, therefore, is calculated as 170.56 km3, which also included 12.3 km3 as environmental flows for the province of Sindh. Punjab had the highest water requirements (109.48 km3), followed by Sindh (43.07 km3), Baluchistan (9.41 km3), and KPK (8.27 km3), as shown in Table 2. In order to check the reliability of our estimated water demands for agriculture, we compared our calculated water demands with other studies. According to the report published by the Ministry of Food, Agriculture and Livestock Islamabad, in 2004, the total agricultural water requirements in Pakistan would be around 150 km3 by 2020 (Hanif et al. 2004). According to Ahmad (2012), ‘the demand of water to meet net crop needs would be 154.5 km3 by 2020’. The estimates in these two reports suggest that our calculation of the agricultural water requirements of 157.25 km3 is reliable.
The canal/irrigation water supplies for Indus River
Various researchers have different views regarding the flows of the Indus River and its tributaries. According to Water and Power Development Authority (WAPDA), the average annual river flow is approximately 138 MAF or 170 km3, of which 128 km3 is diverted for irrigation (Bakhsh et al. 2011). Qureshi (2011) stated that the average flow of the Indus River and its tributaries is 175 km3 of water. Of this, 165 km3 is from the western rivers (Jhelum Chenab and Indus) whereas 10 km3 is from the eastern rivers (Beas, Ravi, and Sutlej). Most of this, 128 km3, is diverted for irrigation; according to Hussain et al. (2011), the total water supply for the agriculture sector is 130 km3. According to another report by the Ministry of Food, Agriculture and Livestock, Islamabad, Pakistan, the total surface water diversions for Pakistan are 130 km3 (Hanif et al. 2004).
Indus river supplies and, consequently, the canal water diversions for agriculture in Pakistan are highly variable, as shown in Figure 3. The canal diversions vary from 137 km3 (111.1 MAF) to 94 km3 (76.2 MAF). Thus, the variability between the highest and lowest canal diversion is 43 km3 (34.9 MAF) due to the stochastic nature of river flows. The canal diversions are also affected due to less storage capacity. From 1975 to 2013, the lowest canal diversion was 94 km3 (76.2 MAF), which severely affected the agricultural sector in Pakistan. 141 km3 (114.32 MAF) of the canal water supplies was apportioned to the provinces according to the Water Accord (Table 1) on the condition that more dams would be constructed and additional storage created. Since the signing of the Water Accord in 1991, the agricultural water demands have increased but no new storage reservoir has been constructed. The median canal diversion from 1975 to 2013 was 125.61 km3 (101.84 MAF), which is less than 141 km3 (114.32 MAF), as decided by the Water Accord.
BANKRUPTCY GAMES APPROACH APPLIED IN WATER RESOURCE ALLOCATION IN THE PROVINCES OF PAKISTAN
This paper aims to show the distribution of limited amount of water available to satisfy the riparians or claimants using the BG procedures. The case of Indus River system is considered. Four different scenarios are developed for the water allocation, as shown in Table 3. First the distribution of water for all four scenarios is done using the five bankruptcy rules given earlier, then, a novel allocation procedure is applied which includes claimants' agricultural productivity. More agricultural productivity would result in higher priority in water allocation.
Reference scenarios . | Water availability (km3) . | Claims (km3) . | Deficit (total) (km3) . |
---|---|---|---|
Scenario 1 (5 in 10) | 125.61 km3 | Punjab (P) = 109.49 km3; Sindh (S) = 43.37 km3; Baluchistan (B) = 9.42 km3; KPK (K) = 8.28 km3; Total = 170.56 km3 | 44.95 |
Scenario 2 (8 in 10) | 116.00 km3 | Punjab (P) = 109.49 km3; Sindh (S) = 43.37 km3; Baluchistan (B) = 9.42 km3; KPK (K) = 8.28 km3; Total = 170.56 km3 | 54.56 |
Scenario 3 (minimum) | 94.00 k | Punjab (P) = 109.49 km3; Sindh (S) = 43.37 km3; Baluchistan (B) = 9.42 km3; KPK (K) = 8.28 km3; Total = 170.56 km3 | 76.56 |
Scenario 4 (5 in 10) (15% increase in water demands under future scenario) | 125.61 km3 | Punjab (P) = 126 km3; Sindh (S) = 49.87 km3; Baluchistan (B) = 10.83 km3; KPK (K) = 9.52 km3; Total = 196.12 km3 | 70.51 |
Reference scenarios . | Water availability (km3) . | Claims (km3) . | Deficit (total) (km3) . |
---|---|---|---|
Scenario 1 (5 in 10) | 125.61 km3 | Punjab (P) = 109.49 km3; Sindh (S) = 43.37 km3; Baluchistan (B) = 9.42 km3; KPK (K) = 8.28 km3; Total = 170.56 km3 | 44.95 |
Scenario 2 (8 in 10) | 116.00 km3 | Punjab (P) = 109.49 km3; Sindh (S) = 43.37 km3; Baluchistan (B) = 9.42 km3; KPK (K) = 8.28 km3; Total = 170.56 km3 | 54.56 |
Scenario 3 (minimum) | 94.00 k | Punjab (P) = 109.49 km3; Sindh (S) = 43.37 km3; Baluchistan (B) = 9.42 km3; KPK (K) = 8.28 km3; Total = 170.56 km3 | 76.56 |
Scenario 4 (5 in 10) (15% increase in water demands under future scenario) | 125.61 km3 | Punjab (P) = 126 km3; Sindh (S) = 49.87 km3; Baluchistan (B) = 10.83 km3; KPK (K) = 9.52 km3; Total = 196.12 km3 | 70.51 |
The core solutions of the cooperative game are defined by the principles of efficiency, rationality, and marginality, as defined in Equations (1)–(3). The lower bound for each user is given by the rationality principle and the upper bound is given by the marginality principle. Table 4 summarizes the results, x(i) represents the water allocation for the ith user expressed in Mm3/year; the parenthesis value represents the assigned percentage in the four deficit scenarios with respect to the available resource. In Table 4, the upper and lower bounds of water allocation inside the core can be considered as limits of ‘feasible values’ that could be accepted by each user.
Scenario-1 (Canal diversion: 5 in 10) | Scenario-2 (Canal diversion: 8 in 10) |
x(P) + x(S) + x(B) + x(K) = 125.61 | x(P) + x(S) + x(B) + x(K) = 116 |
64.54(51%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 109.49 (87%) | 54.93(44%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 109.49 (87%) |
0(0%) ≤ x(S) ≤ 43.37 (34.5%) | 0(0%) ≤ x(S) ≤ 43.37 (34.5%) |
0(0%) ≤ x(B) ≤ 9.42 (7.5%) | 0(0%) ≤ x(B) ≤ 9.42 (7.5%) |
0(0%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 8.28 (6.6%) | 0(0%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 8.28 (6.6%) |
Scenario-3 (Canal diversion: minimum) | Scenario-4 (Canal diversion: 5 in 10) (15% increase in water demands) |
x(P) + x(S) + x(B) + x(K) = 94 | x(P) + x(S) + x(B) + x(K) = 125.61 |
33(35%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 94 (100%) | 55.28(44%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 125.61 (100%) |
0(0%) ≤ x(S) ≤ 43.37 (34.5%) | 0(0%) ≤ x(S) ≤ 43.37 (34.5%) |
0(0%) ≤ x(B) ≤ 9.42 (7.5%) | 0(0%) ≤ x(B) ≤ 9.42 (7.5%) |
0(0%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 8.28 (6.6%) | 0(0%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 8.28 (6.6%) |
Scenario-1 (Canal diversion: 5 in 10) | Scenario-2 (Canal diversion: 8 in 10) |
x(P) + x(S) + x(B) + x(K) = 125.61 | x(P) + x(S) + x(B) + x(K) = 116 |
64.54(51%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 109.49 (87%) | 54.93(44%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 109.49 (87%) |
0(0%) ≤ x(S) ≤ 43.37 (34.5%) | 0(0%) ≤ x(S) ≤ 43.37 (34.5%) |
0(0%) ≤ x(B) ≤ 9.42 (7.5%) | 0(0%) ≤ x(B) ≤ 9.42 (7.5%) |
0(0%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 8.28 (6.6%) | 0(0%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 8.28 (6.6%) |
Scenario-3 (Canal diversion: minimum) | Scenario-4 (Canal diversion: 5 in 10) (15% increase in water demands) |
x(P) + x(S) + x(B) + x(K) = 94 | x(P) + x(S) + x(B) + x(K) = 125.61 |
33(35%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 94 (100%) | 55.28(44%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 125.61 (100%) |
0(0%) ≤ x(S) ≤ 43.37 (34.5%) | 0(0%) ≤ x(S) ≤ 43.37 (34.5%) |
0(0%) ≤ x(B) ≤ 9.42 (7.5%) | 0(0%) ≤ x(B) ≤ 9.42 (7.5%) |
0(0%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 8.28 (6.6%) | 0(0%) ≤ x(P) ≤ 8.28 (6.6%) |
Figure 4 summarizes the results of five bankruptcy rules under different scenarios. These results are expressed as percentage values. These values are therefore not compared to the total assets but to the user's claims. For example, in Scenario 1, according to proportionate rule, all four provinces, namely, Punjab, Sindh, Baluchistan, and KPK are awarded 73% of their claims. Similarly, in Scenario 1, according to Piniles' rule, Punjab is awarded 58% of its claims whereas Sindh, Baluchistan, and KPK are awarded 100% of their claims. It is evident from Figure 4 that a fixed proportional allocation that shares the deficit among users is given by the PROP rule. CEA favors the agents having small claims whereas CEL favors the agents having large claims. Talmud and Piniles' rules have somewhat similar results and their results fall in between CEL and PROP rules.
The crop production per acre feet of water, weights, and the weighted water demands are shown in Table 5. The bankruptcy rules are then applied considering the weighted water demands and the results are shown in Figure 5. A comparison between Figures 4 and 5 highlights how weighted water requests modify BG assignments including priorities. From Figure 5, it is evident that due to their higher weights, KPK and Baluchistan are given more preference and hence their satisfaction level is more than Punjab and Sindh in almost all the bankruptcy rules, even when considering the minimum canal water diversions (Scenario 3). Moreover, the allocation rules used here give solutions that are still inside the core boundaries (Table 4) and they belong to the set of admissible solutions satisfying efficiency, rationality, and marginality principles. The main advantage of the weighted bankruptcy rules as compared with conventional ones is that it allows consideration of the agricultural productivity of states as an important factor which may facilitate negotiations among riparian countries or provinces.
. | Punjab (P) . | Sindh (S) . | Baluchistan (B) . | KPK (K) . | Total . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Crop production per acre feet of water (US$) | 189 | 80 | 277 | 307 | – |
Weight | 1.89 | 0.80 | 2.77 | 3.07 | – |
Actual water demand (km3/year) Scenario 1, 2, and 3 | 109.49 | 43.37 | 9.42 | 8.28 | 170.56 |
Weighted water demand (km3/year) Scenario 1, 2, and 3 | 207.0 | 34.7 | 26.0 | 25.4 | 293.1 |
Actual water demand (km3/year) Scenario 4 | 126 | 49.87 | 10.83 | 9.52 | 196.12 |
Weighted water demand (km3/year) Scenario 4 | 238.1 | 40 | 30 | 29.2 | 337.3 |
. | Punjab (P) . | Sindh (S) . | Baluchistan (B) . | KPK (K) . | Total . |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Crop production per acre feet of water (US$) | 189 | 80 | 277 | 307 | – |
Weight | 1.89 | 0.80 | 2.77 | 3.07 | – |
Actual water demand (km3/year) Scenario 1, 2, and 3 | 109.49 | 43.37 | 9.42 | 8.28 | 170.56 |
Weighted water demand (km3/year) Scenario 1, 2, and 3 | 207.0 | 34.7 | 26.0 | 25.4 | 293.1 |
Actual water demand (km3/year) Scenario 4 | 126 | 49.87 | 10.83 | 9.52 | 196.12 |
Weighted water demand (km3/year) Scenario 4 | 238.1 | 40 | 30 | 29.2 | 337.3 |
In the Indus River Basin, climate change can have undesirable effects. Increased temperature and evapotranspiration and reduced precipitation may result in considerable changes in river runoff. It is predicted that runoff will decrease in the range of 5–40% for a majority of the basin for the period 2090–2099 relative to 1980–1999 (Granit & Joyce 2012). Therefore, for further studies, it is proposed to consider the impact of climate change on the total flow and contribution rate of states to allocate the shared water among states according to different schemes. It can potentially decrease future conflict over the negative aspects of climate change. However, other measures will be required as well, such as increasing water use efficiency, improving water resource management (Granit & Joyce 2012).
Due to the complex nature of transboundary water allocation, we cannot be certain that the simple bankruptcy rules and the weighted bankruptcy rules will be able to solve all the issues related to shared water resource allocation. Water sharing is viewed differently by the people living in different regions, hence their appreciation of the resource and the values attributed to the various functions of the water as a result of cultural, climatic, and economic circumstances.
CONCLUSIONS
The water scarcity issue can be a cause of conflict among riparian countries, states, or provinces. This paper examined the utility of bankruptcy rules in addressing the supply–demand gap in shared rivers. Five bankruptcy rules were used in this study to resolve the conflict between the provinces of Pakistan over the allocation of water. Apart from water scarcity, the uncertain and stochastic nature of rivers and the increasing water demands due to climate change makes the water sharing mechanism more complex and challenging. The water allocation mechanism described in this study uses the bankruptcy game (BG) technique, which is a branch of cooperative game theory. This approach can be a useful tool for decision-making when it comes to the sharing of water resources under critical scarce conditions for complex water resource systems having competing water demands. Using the five bankruptcy rules, the water distribution was done among the four provinces of Pakistan under four different critical scenarios. Also, the bankruptcy rules were applied again, which included the water allocation priorities favoring the users which have a higher agricultural productivity. From the results obtained, it can be seen that the simple bankruptcy rules and weighted bankruptcy rules can be important tools for decision-makers to allocate water in critical scarcity and uncertain conditions between the different water users. Although appropriate vision is provided by the allocation rules for the conflict management of transboundary water resources, the distribution of water among riparians can be a complex problem that cannot be solved only by mathematical methods; therefore, water diplomacy and negotiation between the provinces of Pakistan are suggested, which would help them to develop a consensus and reach an agreement. This method can help policy-makers to facilitate negotiation in managing conflict and dispute over water resources allocation problems. It is a tool to create more options that may assist riparian countries when negotiations are tedious. However, some fine-tuning may still be necessary. Further studies may address the limitations of this study and consider some additional influential factors such as the impacts of climate change, reliable relative weights of states, and socio-political aspects of the basin as well as the effects of external powers.