In response to rapidly growing energy demands, Chinese authorities plan to invest more in hydropower development. However, there are concerns about the possible effects on macroeconomy. This paper uses SinoTERM, a dynamic multi-regional computable general equilibrium model (CGE) of the Chinese economy, to analyze the economic impact of large hydropower development projects. The model features regional labor market dynamics and an electricity subdivision module with substitutability between various types of electricity generation. The results suggest that hydropower development will boost economic growth in the project region. Most sectors in the project region will benefit from the hydropower development such as other services, health, and education, while some sectors will suffer a loss in output because of the substantial increase in real wages. For the national, every 10,000 yuan investment can drive the national GDP growth of 1,000 yuan, and the cost is expected to be recovered in ten years. By the end of 2040, the real national wage will be around 0.16% higher than the baseline scenario. The project could only be justified if net environmental benefits outweigh this loss.

  • This paper used the SinoTERM model to assess the regional and national economic impacts of a large hydropower development project.

  • This SinoTERM model is dynamic through labor and capital year-by-year adjustments and accumulation. So this model could simulate long-term costs and benefits associated with dam development.

Many developing countries are investing in hydropower to increase the degree of electrification and improve national development (Siciliano et al., 2015). China's burgeoning economic growth has been accompanied by soaring demand for electricity. In response to worsening pollution in China as a result of increased coal-fired electricity generation (Zou, et al., 2021), In September 2020, At the UN General Assembly, China announced to the world the goal of achieving carbon peak by 2030 and carbon neutral by 2060. The Chinese government started a new long-term renewable resources investment plan in its 14th ‘Five Year Plan’ period. By 2030, non-fossil energy will account for about 25 percent of primary energy consumption, this will greatly promote the development of hydropower. Compared with other energy sources, hydropower resource has the following characteristics: low cost, near-zero pollution emissions, and the ability to respond quickly to peak loads. These characteristics make it a very valuable resource (Cheng et al., 2012; Fujimoria et al., 2014). According to the ‘14th ‘Five Year’ Electric Power Plan in China’ (National Energy Administration, 2016) and ‘Energy Development Strategy Plan’1, Hydropower is a priority for all types of power generation.

Hydropower projects have a significant economic impact on their regions, even nationally and globally (Cestti & Malik, 2012). There are some researches in the area of the economic impact of hydropower development projects. Goldsmith & Hildyard (1984) provided an overview of the impacts and costs of various large dam projects. Mallakh (1959) and Owen (1964) presented comprehensive economic analyses of how the Egyptian economy was affected by the High Aswan project. The first dam built in Laos was the NamNgum Dam, which was evaluated by the World Bank (2004). The conclusion of the research is that the NamNgum dam's macroeconomic impact on Loas would be substantial. Elokhin & Goruleva (1969) found out that the Volga-Kama dam system had generated multiple economic benefits in the form of higher electric power output, higher capacity of river transport, and a further improvement in water supply for agriculture, industry and household use. Ortolano et al. (2000) analyzed the multiplier effects of the Grand Coulee Dam, including irrigation, hydropower, flood control, recreation, ecological effects, and social-economic effects. The dam generates between 1.5 to 1.7 dollars of economic benefits for each dollar invested. Bhatia et al. (2008) noted that the benefits of dams include increased irrigation water and industrial water and water for flood protection, and reduced vulnerability to droughts, and they found that the benefit from the dams in the Sub-Medio Sao Francisco may have accounted for 1.2% to 6% of GDP. Some researchers also conduct researches on trade-off among economic, environmental impact, and cost of the dam. For example, For the relicensing agreement for two hydroelectric dams in Michigan, Kotchen et al. (2006) conducted a cost-benefit analysis. The result suggests that the total revenue generated is more than twice the cost of production. Morimoto (2013) proposed a project assessment tool to quantitatively examines the economic and social impact of hydropower development in a holistic approach. The results of Xia et al. (2020) indicated that the construction of large hydropower projects is beneficial for social welfare promotion, but the enhancement does not appear immediately at the startup but with a lag; negative externalities are prominent in the early phases while positive ones account for a major proportion in the late phases. The results show that there are obvious mutual constraints among the economic, environmental, and social objectives of hydropower development.

The above-mentioned studies used statistics or partial quantitative methods to estimate the impact of hydropower development on the economy. Since the impacts of dams will infiltrate many aspects of the economy through industrial connections, comprehensive evaluation with detailed information on the sectors is necessary. In analyzing chemical energy problems, much computable general equilibrium (CGE) models that have been developed can be used. Examples of these studies can be found through Bhattacharyya (1996), McDougall (1993), Burniaux & Truong (2002), and Adams et al. (2003) findings. These studies suggest the idea of integrating inter-fuel, factor-energy substitution, and multi-vehicle alternatives. CGE models with multiple sectors have been used to explore the economic influence of hydropower development in several studies. For example, Strzepek et al. (2008) used a single-region CGE model to estimate the economic impact of the High Aswan Dam. Wittwer (2009) used a multi-regional and dynamic CGE model when estimating the impact of the construction of the Traveston dam in South-East Queensland. He concluded that the magnitude of the project's net welfare benefits depends on basic assumptions about future rainfall patterns. Levent (2010) used a dynamic single-region CGE model of the Turkish economy to analyze the potential long-term impacts of hydropower. The simulation results showed that hydropower would increase real GDP by 0.14% per year, real consumption by 0.13%, and real investment by 0.07% in 2020. However, a single-region model cannot reflect the impact of a hydropower project on other regions. The impacts of a dam usually spread to other regions, indicating a need for multi-regional CGE models to comprehensively assess regional impacts. Tewodros et al. (2015) assessed the direct and indirect impact of the Grand Ethiopian Renaissance Dam (GERD) through a multi-regional CGE model. By the time GERD became operational, its negative impact on the Egyptian economy had begun to be reversed; GERD had produced good economic benefits and improved the economy and welfare of all East Nile countries. Liu et al. (2015) applied a static multi-regional CGE model that provides a lot of information about the region to assess the economic and social impact of hydropower development in China. However, Liu's research used a static model. Large hydropower project often takes several years to construct, and the operational phases last for 50 years or more.

Most of the costs and benefits associated with dam development have a long-time span. Dynamic linkages and year-by-year adjustments are necessary. Most existing research simulate dam development at specific one year, these studies could not simulate and estimate the long-time and dynamic impact on the economy. In addition, the existing research on the impact of dam development appears to pay little attention to the following: (1) substitution between various types of electricity sources; differentiated pricing of different types of electricity sources; (2) power generation sectors. In order to estimating the long-time economic impact of large hydropower projects, we use a dynamic multi-regional model of China – SinoTERM (The Enormous Regional Model), we extend the old version of SinoTERM by introducing regional labor market dynamics and an electricity subdivision module with substitutability between various types of electricity generation. The extended SinoTERM model includes detailed information of sectors and regions (electricity generation is disaggregated into four sectors: Coal-electricity, which uses coal to generate electricity; Hydroelectricity, nuclear electricity, and renewable and gas electricity), especially power generation sectors (all power generation industries are only allowed to sell to the distribution industry). According to CES (Constant Alternative Elasticity), the resources of the power distribution industry come from these power generation industries. This model could simulate continuous multiphase economy impact from hydropower, include many indirect and induced effects.

The rest of this article is organized as follows: Section 2, we describe the SinoTERM model and its extension; Section 3 discusses the development of the baseline scenario and policy scenario. Simulation results are discussed in Section 4. Discussions is displayed in Section 5 and Section 6 is conclusions.

SinoTERM model

SinoTERM is a dynamic multi-regional Chinese economic model developed by the Australian Policy Research Center. It is based on the Enormous Regional Model of the Australian economy, the Australian TERM. The theory of the SinoTERM model is similar to the national dynamic CGE models such as MONASH (Dixon & Rimmer, 2002; Horridge et al., 2005) and CHINAGEM (Mai et al., 2010) except that it involves multiple regions. In fact, we treat each region in the model as a separate economy, and these economies are connected through trade (Wittwer & Horridge, 2008, 2010). When a shock is given to a specific region, with the economic connections among the regions, the SinoTERM model allows us to analyze the economic impacts of the shock on all the regions and the nation as a whole.

The equation system of SinoTERM described in Horridge et al. (2005) is similar to other models in the TERM series. The features of the SinoTERM model, which are summarized in Wittwer & Horridge (2008), include a complete input-output database, inter-regional trade matrix, and behavioral equations for each region. The master databases of SinoTERM contains input-output data for 137 industries in 31 regions of China. It includes detailed profit margin information, including railways, highways, waterways and air transportation, pipelines, warehousing, trade (retail and wholesale), and insurance. In order to allow for the possibility of changes in specific items between regions and users (in raw data or as part of a simulation), the database contains detailed tax rate matrices. The equations in the model are linearized for simplicity, which combined with accuracy via multi-step solution methods, ensures model efficiency through the use of GEMPACK software (Horridge et al., 2013).

Dynamics have been added to SinoTERM (Wittwer et al., 2005), following Dixon & Rimmer (2002). Linking capital and investment over time is the main dynamic mechanism. Under the dynamic approach, it is agreed that the construction and operation stages of a specific project in the simulation can be expressed year by year. Since the model is subject to policy impacts, the rate of return on capital will gradually be adjusted. Using this method allows us to model some adjustment costs. The dynamic mechanism of accumulation of net foreign assets is also added to the SinoTERM model so that considering the highly relevant characteristics of China's huge trade surplus, net foreign income is transformed into the disposable income of each family.

Model extensions

Electricity subdivision module

An old version of the SinoTERM model analyzed issues such as the construction of the Chongqing-Lichuan Railway (Horridge & Pearson, 2011) and agricultural productivity (Wittwer & Horridge, 2008, 2010). The old version of SinoTERM did not include inter-fuel substitutability in electricity generation. For the present application, according to the MMRF-Green (Adams et al., 2003) method, we divided the composite power sector into power generation and distribution. The power generation industry is differentiated according to the type of material used. The end-use supplier provides the purchased electricity to the power user. When purchasing electricity, it can replace different power generation technologies in response to changes in the cost of generating electricity.

In the SinoTERM model, electricity generation is disaggregated into four sectors: Coal-electricity, which uses coal to generate electricity; Hydroelectricity, nuclear electricity, and renewable and gas electricity. All power generation industries are only allowed to sell to the distribution industry. According to CES (Constant Alternative Elasticity), the resources of the power distribution industry come from these power generation industries. In the configuration, we set the value of the substitution elasticity between the different electricity generation sectors at 22. The structure of the production for the industry is shown in Figure 1.

Fig. 1

Structure of the production in the SinoTERM model.

Fig. 1

Structure of the production in the SinoTERM model.

Close modal

In terms of model design, under nested production functions, it is assumed that the production sector maximizes profits. The importance of splitting electricity into different types is that it enables us to provide different cost structures and investigate the substitute relationship for different types of electricity generation. For example, coal-generating electricity uses coal as the main input. Nuclear and hydroelectric generations are more capital intensive than other forms of generation.

Regional labor market dynamics

Following Wittwer (2009), regional labor market dynamics are also introduced into the SinoTERM model. As time goes by, in order to cope with the global shock, the regional labor force will be partially adjusted. The regional labor market adjustment mechanism in SinoTERM, in level form, is given by:
(1)

If in region r, relative to the predicted period t, the policy shock weakens the labor market, then in the policy scenario, the real wage is lower than the forecast wage . In addition, relative to forecast levels and , in the labor market, the gap between labor market demand and supply will expand. In the next few years, due to further declines in real wages, the gap between demand and supply will fall further to return to the predicted level. The speed of labor market adjustment is controlled by the positive parameter γ.

The regional labor supply equation is as follows:
(2)

The deviation of regional real wages relative to the predicted national real wages determines the deviation from the forecast caused by the policy shock of regional labor supply. In (2), is a measure of the total work responsiveness of all regions to real wages, among which γ is a positive parameter and is the share of region q in national employment. This equation means that the labor supply in a given area will decline while other areas will increase. Combining (1) and (2), if you want to adjust the labor market in a particular area, you should first increase unemployment and lower real wages. Eventually, unemployment will return to the predicted level with lower real wages. As real wages decline relative to the basic situation, the labor supply in the region will also decline. Under this theory, the adjustment of the long-term labor market depends on the combination of labor migration between regions and changes in real wage differences.

Regions and sectors

The value matrix is divided into commodities, industries, sources, and regions, and these are included in the database of the SinoTERM model. The model contains quantity and price variables for each of these flows. In order to focus on the hydropower development issue, shorten the solution time, and present the simulation results in a targeted manner, we aggregate the sectors and regions to manageable dimensions while retaining details in sectors and regions of interest. We aggregate the master SinoTERM database of 137 sectors and 31 regions to 36 sectors and 6 regions, which include (1) the project region in Southwest China; (2) the rest of Southwest China; (3) South China (Guangdong, Guangxi, and Hainan); (4) Central China (Chongqing, Jiangxi, Henan, Hubei, and Hunan); (5) East China (Shanghai, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, and Anhui) and (6) the rest of China. The 36 sectors are listed in Supplementary Material, Appendix A.

This paper selected the construction of a dam and hydropower plant in the southwest of China as a case study3. With numerous rivers and intertwined lakes, the region has abundant potential hydropower resources. Other characteristics of the region are that it is rich in natural resources with a low degree of exploration and development, especially mineral resources, chromium, copper, and iron, etc. Transport and communications in the region are limited. Agriculture in the region uses traditional labor, with little agricultural machinery or modern agricultural technology. The per capita GDP of the region is less than 60% of the national average, and the per capita disposable income is only 75% of the national average. Generally speaking, the region is underdeveloped.

According to the Chinese government's plan, a total amount of 1,000 billion RMB would be invested in the project region to build a hydropower station from 2015 to 2024. Its total installed capacity is 100 sets of water wheel turbines of 500,000 Kw. If the number of hours of the hydropower equipment operation increases to 6,000 h, the station will generate 300 billion KWh of electricity annually in the operational phase from 2025.

To analyze the economic effects of hydropower development, we must first make a prediction for the basic case, that is, the scenario of conducting daily business without the construction and operation of a specific hydroelectric power station. Then we conduct strategic simulations and make alternative predictions for the hydropower station. The effects of the hydropower construction and operation on the project region, other regions, and the nation as a whole are measured by deviations of variables in the alternative forecast from their baseline levels.

Baseline scenario

The baseline scenario is divided into two periods: the first ‘historical’ period from 2007 to 2016 and the second ‘forecast’ period from 2017 to 2040. For the ‘historical’ period, since the database of the SinoTERM model in this paper was based on China's 2007 Input-Output Tables4, we updated the SinoTERM model to 20165, and the annual growth rates of economic variables from 2007 to 2016 were assigned according to their actual numbers published in China Statistical Yearbooks by the National Bureau of Statistics (NBS, various years) and in the United Nations commodity trade database6.

Calibration of GDP growth and its components

For the forecast period, the annual growth rates of GDP (Table 1) are from the ‘13th five-year plan’ and ‘2030 Outlook’ (NDRC, 2016). For the growth of the components of GDP regarding expenditure, we assume that household consumption is growing faster than investment. The reason is that China's growth model is changing from investment-driven growth to consumption-driven growth. The other reason is that with continued economic growth and increased income the consumption of income elastic goods and services will grow more rapidly than the consumption of income inelastic goods and services. With faster growth of consumption, the share of household consumption in GDP will become higher over time while the shares of investment and net exports will be falling (Table 2).

Table 1

The grow rates of GDP of China from 2007 to 2040.

Years (historical period)Growth rateYears (forecast period)Growth rate
2007 14.2% 2016 6.7% 
2008 9.6% 2017 6.7% 
2009 9.2% 2018 6.7% 
2010 10.6% 2019 6.6% 
2011 9.5% 2020 6.4% 
2012 7.8% 2021–2025 6.4% 
2013 7.7% 2026–2030 5.0% 
2014 7.3% 2031–2035 4.3% 
2015 6.9% 2036–2040 4.3% 
Years (historical period)Growth rateYears (forecast period)Growth rate
2007 14.2% 2016 6.7% 
2008 9.6% 2017 6.7% 
2009 9.2% 2018 6.7% 
2010 10.6% 2019 6.6% 
2011 9.5% 2020 6.4% 
2012 7.8% 2021–2025 6.4% 
2013 7.7% 2026–2030 5.0% 
2014 7.3% 2031–2035 4.3% 
2015 6.9% 2036–2040 4.3% 

Source: data for historical period are from China Statistical yearbooks and for forecast period are from 13th five-year plan and 2030 outlook (NDRC, 2016) and the World Bank9. The 2007–2016 data are real data. The 2017–2040 data are forecast data.

Table 2

The shares of GDP components.

20132015202020302040
Household consumption 33% 34% 38% 47% 54% 
Investment 27% 27% 25% 21% 16% 
Government consumption 11% 11% 11% 12% 12% 
Net export 29% 28% 26% 20% 18% 
GDP 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 
20132015202020302040
Household consumption 33% 34% 38% 47% 54% 
Investment 27% 27% 25% 21% 16% 
Government consumption 11% 11% 11% 12% 12% 
Net export 29% 28% 26% 20% 18% 
GDP 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 

Source: simulation result of baseline scenario.

Calibration of the electricity sectors

Concerning the demand for electricity, we assume in the baseline that electricity demand may, at least in the longer run, grow at a slower rate than industrial output or income growth in China. This is based on two features of income growth: (1) the movement towards consumption of services; and (2) the impact of technological change. Technological change that reduces electricity inputs per unit of output can be accelerated by appropriate electricity pricing, which increases the incentive for industries to improve energy efficiency. For example, new widescreen television sets are more energy-efficient than those of several years ago due to LED technology. Lighting has also experienced substantial efficiency gains with the growing use of LED technology. New washing machines and refrigerators are more energy-efficient than those of a decade ago. Sectors are also becoming more energy-efficient so that as industrial output grows, industrial demand for electricity will grow at a slower rate than output.

There are many opportunities to increase the utilization of base-load electricity. Many electricity authorities around the world have introduced electricity pricing, which varies according to the time of day. This encourages consumers to delay the use of appliances such as dishwashing machines until a lower night tariff applies. One of the attractions of electric cars, for example, is that they could be charged overnight when factories are not operating, thereby increasing the utilization of off-peak electricity and reducing the marginal impact of cars on energy consumption.

An important component of supplying electricity to users is electricity transmission. This is particularly the case in China, in which there are substantial coalfields in the northeast and north and substantial water resources in the southwest, but most industrial activity and households are located in the east. Electricity grids increase the effective supply of generated electricity. A well-dispersed grid enables generators from one region to contribute to the needs of another region. For example, hydropower generation output has seasonal variations as water volumes peak after snow melts. At other times, users within a grid will rely more heavily on electricity sourced from elsewhere.

According to the national accounts, the value-add of the utility sectors totaled almost 1,130 billion RMB in 20127. We updated the SinoTERM model so that the value-add of the electricity sectors in 2012 was around 1,200 billion RMB. We aim in this study to impose the same valuation on electricity as appears in the national accounts. In the SinoTERM database, this corresponds to 4,977 billion kWh of generating capacity in 2012 (IEA, 2016).

In summary, gains in energy efficiency in industrial processes and households, the increased uptake of solar energy, time-of-use pricing, and improved electricity grids will all contribute to a lessening of future electricity-generating requirements relative to otherwise. We assume that in the forecast period, electricity consumption will peak around 20308 and then begin to decline due to slower economic growth and high efficiency from technological progress. The baseline simulation shows that there will be 11,000 billion kWh of electricity demand by 2030 and 10,200 billion kWh by 2040 (Table 3) according to Liu (2012) and ‘Research on Medium and Long-term Development Strategy of China's Energy (2030, 2050)’ conducted by the CAE (the Chinese Academy of Engineering, 2011). China's electricity demand see in Table 3.

Table 3

China's electricity demand (billion kWh) in the baseline scenario.

20202025203020352040
Household 1,220 1,300 1,400 1,400 1,400 
Production 4,780 7,700 9,600 9,100 8,800 
Total 6,000 9,000 11,000 10,500 10,200 
20202025203020352040
Household 1,220 1,300 1,400 1,400 1,400 
Production 4,780 7,700 9,600 9,100 8,800 
Total 6,000 9,000 11,000 10,500 10,200 

Source: total electricity demand Liu (2012) and ‘Research on Medium and Long-term Development Strategy of China's Energy (2030, 2050)’.

In 2009, China announced a goal to reduce the carbon intensity of GDP and increase the share of non-fossil fuels. This goal is very ambitious (NDRC, 2010). Recently submitted a document called ‘United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change ‘(UNFCCC, 2015), which is a document drawn up by nationally determined contributions. The document promises that China will increase the proportion of non-fossil energy in its main energy consumption to about 20% by 2030 (UNFCCC, 2015). By the end of 2040, we plan to bring the total installed nuclear power capacity to 201GW, accounting for 6.8% of the total power generation (Table 4), and the total installed hydropower capacity to 568GW, accounting for 15.6% of the total power generation.

Table 4

Installed capacity of non-fossil power (GW).

CoalOilGasHydroNuclearWindBiomassSolar
2010 700 1.14 31 260 12 48 
2015 823 1.17 100 306 40 105 31 42 
2020 902 1.14 199 360 64 249 58 105 
2030 1,122 1.32 274 497 113 593 69 310 
2040 1,083 1.07 297 568 201 847 102 777 
CoalOilGasHydroNuclearWindBiomassSolar
2010 700 1.14 31 260 12 48 
2015 823 1.17 100 306 40 105 31 42 
2020 902 1.14 199 360 64 249 58 105 
2030 1,122 1.32 274 497 113 593 69 310 
2040 1,083 1.07 297 568 201 847 102 777 

Data source: from Dai et al. (2016).

In addition, some technologies such as geothermal, wave, and chemical storage in the power sector model are too small to be considered in the CGE model.

Policy scenario set

The planned construction of the hydropower station is from 2015 to 2024. The operation of the hydropower station commences in 2025. There is a 10-year lag between investment and the additional capacity becoming operational. A lag of this length will reduce the net returns from this project.

A key assumption of this simulation is that labor for building the hydropower station is supplied by the project region and others due to a shortage of labor in the project region. That is, at the beginning of the construction phase, there is a planned movement of labor from the rest of China to the project region.

The hydropower project involves large up-front investment costs, most of which are related to financing the dam and plant construction, electricity grid, and other infrastructure constructions such as roads to the dam (Table 5). Apart from the investment costs, the other main cost is maintenance, including repairs and insurance during the operation period. The annual investment scheme is shown in Table 5. The average electricity generated annually will be about 300 billion kWh when the hydropower station is fully operational from 2030 (Table 6).

Table 5

The investment (million RMB) allocation of hydropower station in project region.

YearsHydropower plantHydropower equipmentElectricity gridInfrastructureTotal investment
2015 76,200 38,400 2,400 3,000 120,000 
2016 76,200 38,400 2,400 3,000 120,000 
2017 63,500 32,000 4,500 100,000 
2018 50,800 25,600 3,600 80,000 
2019 50,800 25,600 3,600 80,000 
2020 44,450 22,400 3,150 70,000 
2021 44,450 22,400 3,150 70,000 
2022 44,450 22,400 3,150 70,000 
2023 44,450 22,400 3,150 70,000 
2024 38,100 19,200 2,700 60,000 
2025 38,100 19,200 2,700 60,000 
2026 25,400 12,800 1,800 40,000 
2027 12,700 6,400 900 20,000 
2028 9,525 4,800 675 15,000 
2029 9,525 4,800 675 15,000 
2030 6,350 3,200 450 10,000 
2031–40 64 32 100 
YearsHydropower plantHydropower equipmentElectricity gridInfrastructureTotal investment
2015 76,200 38,400 2,400 3,000 120,000 
2016 76,200 38,400 2,400 3,000 120,000 
2017 63,500 32,000 4,500 100,000 
2018 50,800 25,600 3,600 80,000 
2019 50,800 25,600 3,600 80,000 
2020 44,450 22,400 3,150 70,000 
2021 44,450 22,400 3,150 70,000 
2022 44,450 22,400 3,150 70,000 
2023 44,450 22,400 3,150 70,000 
2024 38,100 19,200 2,700 60,000 
2025 38,100 19,200 2,700 60,000 
2026 25,400 12,800 1,800 40,000 
2027 12,700 6,400 900 20,000 
2028 9,525 4,800 675 15,000 
2029 9,525 4,800 675 15,000 
2030 6,350 3,200 450 10,000 
2031–40 64 32 100 

Source: The Draft Plan of Hydropower Development in the project region.

Table 6

The electricity generation of the hydropower station (billion kWh).

YearsElectricity generationYearsElectricity generation
2025 60 2033 290 
2026 110 2034 300 
2027 140 2035 300 
2028 140 2036 300 
2029 230 2037 300 
2030 280 2038 300 
2031 280 2039 300 
2032 280 2040 300 
YearsElectricity generationYearsElectricity generation
2025 60 2033 290 
2026 110 2034 300 
2027 140 2035 300 
2028 140 2036 300 
2029 230 2037 300 
2030 280 2038 300 
2031 280 2039 300 
2032 280 2040 300 

Source: The Draft Plan of Hydropower Development in the project region.

We assume that the electricity generated from the proposed hydropower station from 2025 will be transmitted to South China, Central China, and East China. The shares of the electricity received by these three regions are 60, 20, and 20%, respectively.

Because of the increasing demand for labor in the project region, as a result of the huge amount of investment in hydropower development, the labor cost, at least in the initial several years of dam construction,, will increase. As a result, some sectors will be affected negatively. In the policy scenario in the operation period, we assume that some of sales of electricity will be used to fund additional investment across a number of ‘target’ sectors in the project region such as education, health, and other service sectors.

Macroeconomic impacts on the nation

Impact on the national labor market and real GDP

The macroeconomic effect of the huge regional project in hydropower development is relatively small at the national level. The inflow of labor to the project region reduces the labor supply in other regions. But for the nation as a whole, the total labor supply will be fixed in the long run. The increased labor demands generated from the massive construction project in the project region will raise employment initially and strengthen the national labor market from 2015 until 2024 (Figure 2). The sluggish adjustment in real wages implies that real wages persist above the baseline scenario, even as expenditure on the construction phase will be reduced around 2020. This means that national employment will fall slightly below the baseline scenario in the later years of the construction phase as the labor market weakens. The operational phase will raise working capital and provide a technological gain as additional electricity generation commences. This will raise the marginal product of labor and therefore move real wages further above the baseline scenario. By the end of 2040, the real national wage will be around 0.16% higher than the baseline scenario (Figure 2). Employment will remain around 0.02% below the base, implying that a little further downward adjustment of wages will be required before it returns to base.

Fig. 2

National labor market (cumulative deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Fig. 2

National labor market (cumulative deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Close modal

Figure 3 shows the impact of the construction and operational phases of the project on national GDP. GDP (Y) is defined as a function of the underlying technology A, capital K and labor L, Y= 1/A*F (K, L). GDP is chiefly affected by capital K and labor L. Although capital rises above the baseline scenario during the construction phase, the capital constructed by this project does not become operational until 2025. Therefore, real GDP falls slightly below the baseline scenario during the construction phase. Once the capital becomes operational, there is a jump in real GDP and a technological gain reflecting the commencement of electricity generation. The national real GDP will be between 0.04% and 0.06% higher than the baseline during the operational phase (K will be between 0.10% and 0.11% higher). Not considering the other case, every 10,000 yuan static investment can drive the national GDP growth of 1,000 yuan, and the cost is expected to be recovered in ten years (it is rough averages).

Fig. 3

National GDP in the policy scenario (cumulative deviation from baseline forecast). Source: Simulation results.

Fig. 3

National GDP in the policy scenario (cumulative deviation from baseline forecast). Source: Simulation results.

Close modal

Impacts on national welfare

At the national level, the diversion of labor from other regions reduces income in the rest of China during the construction phase. Other regions of China obtain benefit from the increase in electricity supplied by the project region during the operational phase.

We use real household consumption and net foreign liability to measure national welfare. For the equation of national welfare, please refer to Supplementary Material, Appendix B.

The formal measure of welfare using the equation (see Supplementary Material, Appendix B) is close to minus 12.6 billion RMB. The main reason for the national welfare loss arises from the long lag between commencing construction and the operation of the hydropower station. National welfare will be positive in the operational phase (10 years). Although the value of electricity in the model has been calibrated so as to align with the latest available data from China's national accounts, it is possible that electricity generated by the project could be more valuable to the economy than that modeled. In particular, fossil-fueled electricity generation in the future may be subjected to a pollution tax, raising the competitiveness of hydropower as ‘clean’ electricity. In this case, the national welfare gain will be greater after the operation of the hydropower station.

Moreover, while we would expect investments in remote regions to be relatively expensive, it is also possible that earnings on investment in more densely populated regions of China could fall in the future due to problems arising from pollution and congestion. If so, the welfare outcome of this project would improve.

Impacts on national electricity security

Hydropower development in the project region will increase the nation's electricity supply. The electricity supply will be 0.28% higher in the first year of the operational phase, and by the end of 2040, the electricity supply will be 0.89% higher than in the baseline scenario.

Our SinoTERM model incorporates an electricity subdivision module that considers a substitution relationship between various types of electricity generation. The increase in hydroelectricity will take the place of other types of electricity. Figure 4 shows that hydroelectricity replacing coal electricity makes a decrease in the output of coal electricity from a nationwide perspective. By the end of 2040, the output of coal electricity will be 0.51% lower than the baseline scenario, gas and renewable electric and nuclear electricity will be 0.52% and 1.14% lower, respectively (Figure 4). The increase in the hydroelectricity will improve China's electricity infrastructure. The share of coal electricity will fall while the share of electricity generated by clean energy will increase.

Fig. 4

National electricity output in the policy scenario (Cumulative deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Fig. 4

National electricity output in the policy scenario (Cumulative deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Close modal

Impacts on project region

Macroeconomic impact on the project region

The huge investment in the construction of the proposed hydropower station has a significant effect on the project region. We look at the effects on the labor market first. A key assumption is that labor is supplied by other regions. Such a large investment relies on a substantial inflow of workers. That is, at the beginning of the dam construction phase, there is a planned movement of labor from the rest of China to the project region. As a consequence, labor supply plateaus at around 20% or 80,000 workers above the baseline scenario in the region from 2016. The exogenous inflow of labor subdues but does not eliminate real wage growth relative to the baseline scenario during the investment phase in the project region. The project region is an underdeveloped area, implying that base wages are much lower than elsewhere in China. Labor demand (employment) increases because of the construction of the dam. As long as this demand exceeds the labor supply, there is upward pressure on wages. After 2020, rising real wages will bring employment closer to labor supply, thereby subduing further real wages increases. In 2025, the first year of operation of the dam, income generated by the dam will provide additional employment in the project region. Once again, labor demand will jump above labor supply in 2025, imposing additional upward pressure on wages, and real wages will continue to rise. Rising real wages will restrain labor demand and bring employment gradually below the labor supply. Therefore real wages will show a downtrend from 2033 to 2040 (Figure 5). By the end of 2040, the employment of the project region will be about 22% higher than the baseline scenario, and the real wage about 40% higher.

Fig. 5

Labor market in the project region in the policy scenario (Cumulative deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Fig. 5

Labor market in the project region in the policy scenario (Cumulative deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Close modal

The construction of the hydropower station results in a many-fold increase in the project region's aggregate investment from 2015 onwards. As the construction phase winds down (from 40 billion RMB in 2026 to 0.01 billion RMB in 2031), aggregate investment in the region will move back towards the baseline level (Figure 6). The investment will be dominated by the investment imposed directly on dam construction until 2025. From 2026, the second year of the operational phase, we assume that some sales of electricity will be used to fund additional investment across a number of industries in the project region and, to a lesser extent, the rest of the southwest region. This ensures that investment in the project region remains more than 200% above the baseline scenario during the operational phase of the project. Nevertheless, additional demands in the project region continued to be supplied to a considerable extent by increased inter-regional imports. This reliance on trade reduces the extent to which investment and output increase relative to the baseline scenario in the project region's industries other than hydropower generation and electricity distribution.

Fig. 6

Investment in the project region in the policy scenario (Cumulative deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Fig. 6

Investment in the project region in the policy scenario (Cumulative deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Close modal

Household consumption rises with an increase in labor in the early years of the construction phase. From 2017, the inflow of labor led to a 20% in the number of employed people see Figure 5), it moves back in the direction of the baseline as construction expenditures taper off over time. In 2025, the first year of operation of additional hydropower capacity, household consumption will jump further above the baseline scenario, this is because labor supply is on a declining curve. Household consumption will remain around 90% above the base in 2040, implying an increase in consumption per capita in the project region (Figure 7). This is because labor supply (which approximates population) will only be around 25% above the baseline scenario in the same year, implying an increase in per capita consumption in the region of 65% [= 90% − 25%].

Fig. 7

Household consumption in the project region in the policy scenario (Cumulative deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Fig. 7

Household consumption in the project region in the policy scenario (Cumulative deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Close modal

Higher investment growth will bring higher capital stock growth. By the end of the simulation period, capital stock is 52% higher than the baseline scenario.

The huge investment in the project region, particularly the investment in the infrastructure such as road building, will increase the productivity of the region. The simulation shows that by the end of 2040, productivity (technology improvement) will be 63.4% higher than the baseline scenario. Figure 8 also shows that while the dam and hydropower plants are under construction, real GDP in the region will fall below the share-weighted sum of the percentage changes in labor and capital. This is because the capital remains dormant until the project enters the operational phase: dormant capital is equivalent to a technological deterioration. Once the operational phase commences, an increase in capacity utilization (Table 5) implies an increase in productivity. The productivity growth arising from the hydropower plant will eventually make a dominant contribution to the region's real GDP growth while the percentage increases in labor and capital in the region will become much smaller than the region's real GDP during the operational phase. By the end of 2040, GDP will be 114% higher than the baseline scenario (Figure 8). The calculation of real GDP growth in the project region is presented in the Supplementary Material, Appendix C.

Fig. 8

GDP in the project region in the policy scenario (Cumulative deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Fig. 8

GDP in the project region in the policy scenario (Cumulative deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Close modal

Impacts on sectors

Industries that experience increases in output relative to the baseline scenario in the project region are those directly affected by the construction phase, notably construction and transport. During the operational phase, the outputs of hydropower generation and electricity distribution will increase relative to the baseline scenario, in line with the scenario shocks imposed on the model. Other industries with increases in output are those benefiting most directly from the rise in household consumption relative to the baseline scenario or from a targeted investment such as other services, health, and education. However, within the assumptions of the policy scenario, in which investment is directed at physical infrastructure, there are industries within the region that will suffer decreases in output relative to the baseline scenario. This is because the substantial increase in real wages relative to the baseline scenario will reduce the competitiveness of industries not directly benefiting from the project. For instance, livestock industries will suffer from higher wage costs and consequently lose output relative to the baseline scenario (Figure 9).

Fig. 9

Sector outputs of the project region in 2040 in the policy scenario (billion RMB) (Deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Fig. 9

Sector outputs of the project region in 2040 in the policy scenario (billion RMB) (Deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Close modal

In summary, the impact on the output of any industry in the project region is due to several factors: (1) Increased income in the project region as a result of a large investment in the hydroelectricity sector will induce a spending effect, which mainly impacts sectors satisfying household consumption. (2) Increased labor costs induced by the region's investment boom will reduce the competitiveness of lagging sectors and contribute negatively to their output growth. (3) Demands for goods and services associated with the construction industry will rise during the investment phase, which will increase the price of those goods and services, therefore increasing the supply of these goods and services either by import from the region or produced by the project region.

Figure 9 shows the deviations in industry outputs in the project region from the baseline scenario in 2040. Some industries would grow more relative to the baseline scenario during the operational phase if they received larger targeted investment funds. However, no details of targeted investment funds were available for the project when we conducted this research. In this context, it is sufficient to show that targeted investment can spread to regional growth across a number of industries and reduce the potential adverse consequences for industry output of rising real wages relative to the baseline scenario.

Macroeconomic impact on other regions

The excess demands in the project region imply that the region will import heavily from the rest of Southwest China. The gravity assumption of trade within the model ensures that relatively proximal regions will trade more with the project region than more distant regions. Under this assumption, we expect the rest of Southwest China will be affected more than the other regions, employment will rise relative to aa baseline scenario in the construction phase, and will rise further during the operational phase (Figure 10).

Fig. 10

Other regions' labor markets in the policy scenario (Cumulative deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Fig. 10

Other regions' labor markets in the policy scenario (Cumulative deviation from baseline scenario). Source: Policy simulation results.

Close modal

There are two reasons for the wage increase in the operational phase in this region. First, the increased electricity output in the project region will have the effect of strengthening the national labor market, as described above. Second, some of the electricity income will be used to fund investments in the rest of Southwest China. In summary, real wages in the rest of Southwest China will rise more than in the rest of China, albeit from a lower base. The project will also increase employment in the rest of Southwest China relative to the baseline scenario because of the increased investment and export to the project region.

The labor market in the remaining regions will follow a relatively similar pattern, though with smaller percentage changes. Increased labor demands in the early years of the construction phase will raise employment above the baseline scenario until the real wages increase sufficiently to force employment back towards the baseline. The operational phase will strengthen the labor market by raising the marginal product of labor through a combination of increased operating capital and technological gains (i.e., smaller input requirements per unit of output). Employment in other regions will eventually move back towards and below the baseline because of rising real wages (Figure 10).

All regions except for the project region will experience small GDP losses relative to the baseline in the construction phase, arising from the resource squeeze imposed by the demands of the project region (Figure 11).

Fig. 11

GDP in electricity-importing regions in the policy scenario (Cumulative deviation from baseline). Source: Policy simulation results.

Fig. 11

GDP in electricity-importing regions in the policy scenario (Cumulative deviation from baseline). Source: Policy simulation results.

Close modal

In the operational phase, the economies of electricity-importing regions will rise, driven by electricity-lowering costs of production. In Central China, which receives 40% of the project's generated electricity, GDP will be 0.052% higher than the 2040 baseline scenario. Figure 11 shows smaller percentage gains for East China and South China. For the rest of Southwest China, the investment funded from the electricity sale in the operational period plus the cheaper electricity will boost the GDP growth in this area. By the end of 2040, GDP in this region will be 0.72% higher than the baseline scenario.

Comparison with other studies

Our study shows that hydropower dams can promote economic growth, and the results of this research are consistent with the results of previous studies (Wichelns, 2002; Bhatia et al., 2008; Strzepek et al., 2008; Wittwer, 2009; Levent, 2010; Cestti & Malik, 2012; Liu et al., 2015; Ma et al., 2015; Tewodros et al., 2015; Lao, 2016). Using a dynamic multi-regional CGE model of China, this paper explores the economic effect of a 1,000 billion RMB hydropower station development project on the project region, other regions, and the nation as a whole.

Our study shows that the hydropower development project will boost the economic growth of the project region. GDP will be 114% higher than the baseline scenario in the project region. This means that every one RMB of hydropower investment can boost 0.8843 RMB of the GDP for the hydroelectric area. This value is lower than the 0.9676 RMB of Lao (2016) research. One reason for this is that the great mass of electricity generation is transmitted to other regions in China.

Our study shows that national GDP will fall slightly below the baseline scenario during the construction phase, and it will be between 0.04% and 0.06% higher than base during the operational phase. In the research of Liu et al. (2015) and Ma et al. (2015), this trend was also observed. These two studies showed that national GDP was 0.01% higher than the baseline scenario in the construction phase and was 0.10% higher than the baseline scenario in the operational phase. The above studies in section 5.1 used a static model and did not consider the capital stock accumulation and the dormant capital during the construction period. Our study used a dynamic model. As discussed in the previous sections, dormant capital is equivalent to the deterioration of technology. The lag between the construction of the hydropower station and the start of the operation of the station is ten years. That is the reason that, in our study, the national GDP in the construction period will be lower than that in the baseline scenario.

Our study shows that national welfare using the equation (B.1) (see Supplementary Material, Appendix B) is close to minus 12.6 billion RMB. The main reason for this loss is due to the long lag between the construction and operation of the hydropower station, even though national welfare will be positive in the operational phase. In the research conducted by Tewodros et al. (2015), the welfare loss due to large-scale hydropower development projects has also been observed. They found that Egypt experienced a welfare loss of about USD 82 million from the GERD (Grand Ethiopian Renaissance Dam).

Limitations

The current study does not take account of the full economic consequences of a hydropower project. The following sections outline a few of the potential costs and benefits of dam construction not included in the current study, which may lead to overstating – or in some cases, understate – the net benefits of a project.

Environmental impacts

Nevertheless, in terms of environmental sustainability, there are also disputes about large hydropower dams. Since the start of the project, people in the affected areas have suffered from inundation of vegetable gardens, reduced catches, reduced freshwater, and drinking water, and transportation difficulties (Kotchen et al., 2006; McCallum, 2008; Brown et al., 2009; Burke et al., 2009; Bakken et al., 2014).

  • 1.

    Fisheries decline

From a biophysical viewpoint, the main impacts of major hydropower dams relate not only to the fragmentation of river systems but also fragmentation of the vegetation and negative effects on soil and water quality. A decline in fisheries was one of the most important impacts of hydropower projects.

  • 2.

    Sedimentation

The impact of dam construction on siltation will vary between specific projects. Silt flowing freely downstream will provide farmers with soil nutrients. Silt accumulated behind a dam wall has two potentially negative effects. It may reduce land productivity downstream, and it may affect water quality behind the dam wall. Water quality behind the dam wall may also be reduced by algae and chemical runoff that would not have accumulated without the dam (Hu et al., 2009).

  • 3.

    Seismic activity

There are many moderate to very high seismic hazard zones in western China. Earthquakes may damage dams and other structures. Moreover, the weight of water stored in dams may induce additional seismic activity (Yao et al., 2013). Clearly, analysis of seismic activity is outside the domain of economists.

  • 4.

    Flood control

One of the benefits of dam development may be flood mitigation. However, it does not always follow that a dam will make a positive contribution to flood mitigation. The contribution of a dam to flood mitigation may depend on a number of local specific features (Plessis & Viljoen, 1999).

Displaced communities

Massive dam projects may entail the relocation of hundreds of thousands of people. Loss of homes, resettlement, and relocation, changes in livelihood strategies, inadequate compensation, the impact on cultural and social relations,, and the loss of land and water sources all raise social problems (Lerer & Scudder, 1999; Jackson & Sleigh, 2000; WCD, 2000; Brown et al., 2009; Tilt et al., 2009; McDonaldWilmsen & Webber, 2010; Urban et al., 2013; Cooke et al., 2017).

However, the project presented here will be located in a relatively isolated area. It will affect relatively few people directly.

Climate change

Hydropower generation may be affected by climate change and retreating glaciers due to increased river runoff size and seasonal variations, as well as increased reservoir evaporation. These real-world effects, in turn, will have an impact on the economy as a result of changes in producer income and consumer spending. Climate change may have a positive projected effect on electricity generation (Boehlert et al., 2016), and a negative effect on firm power generation, such as Henderson et al. (2013) and Lettenmaier et al. (1999) find that GHG mitigation reduces hydropower generation. In this paper, we do not consider the long-term climate variability. We assume that 300 billion kWh is an average electricity generation for the proposed hydropower station.

Further research

Models developed in this study on the possible impact of large hydropower projects also provide some useful insights. Further work will concentrate on sedimentation and other missing benefits/costs of hydro projects and environmental impacts. For the econometric estimation of certain behavioral parameters used in the model, we still need to do further work. Finally, we must also consider concerns about climate change and how China can benefit from carbon credits. It is beneficial to incorporate carbon emissions into future work.

We extend the old version of SinoTERM by introducing regional labor market dynamics and an electricity subdivision module with substitutability between various types of electricity generation. The extended SinoTERM model includes detailed information of sectors and regions (electricity generation is disaggregated into four sectors: Coal-electricity, which uses coal to generate electricity; Hydroelectricity, nuclear electricity, and renewable and gas electricity), especially power generation sectors (all power generation industries are only allowed to sell to the distribution industry). According to CES (Constant Alternative Elasticity), the resources of the power distribution industry come from these power generation industries. We use the SinoTERM model to assess the long-time economic impacts of a large hydropower development project.

  1. For the nation, the national real GDP will be between 0.04% and 0.06% higher than the baseline during the operational phase, equivalently, for the national, every 10,000 yuan investment can drive the national GDP growth of 1,000 yuan, and the cost is expected to be recovered in ten years. The real national wage will be around 0.16% higher than the baseline scenario in 2040. Employment will remain around 0.02% below the base. The formal measure of welfare using the equation is close to minus 12.6 billion RMB. Most sectors in the project region will benefit from the hydropower development while some sectors will suffer a loss in output because of the substantial increase in real wages.

  2. For project region, the dam will boost the economic growth in the project region significantly, driving real GDP 114% in 2040, the because is that the change of labor (the cumulative deviation of aggregate employment from the baseline scenario) is 24.3%, and the change of capital (the cumulative deviation of aggregate capital from the baseline scenario) is 52.1%, the improvement of technology is 63.4%, in addition to this, the change of ‘tax’ (the cumulative deviation of tax from the baseline scenario) is 16.4%. There are industries increases in output such as construction and transport, other service, health, and education, there are industries within the region that will suffer decreases in output relative to the baseline scenario such as livestock industries will suffer from higher wage costs and consequently lose output relative to the baseline scenario.

  3. For neighboring regions, the neighboring regions will also benefit as a result of increased electricity supply in the operational phase of the proposed hydropower station. In Central China, which receives 40% of the project's generated electricity, GDP will be 0.052% higher than the 2040 baseline scenario. East China and South China gains for shows smaller percentage. For the rest of Southwest China, GDP in this region will be 0.72% higher than the baseline scenario in 2040.

  4. Because of the long lag between the construction and the operational phases, the hydropower development project will bring about a national welfare loss. However, the tendency to use clean energy to replace fossil fuel energy in China will certainly make hydroelectricity more valuable in the future. In this case, the welfare outcome of this project may be improved.

This work was supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China (52009042, 52025093), and the State Key Laboratory of Simulation and Regulation of Water Cycle in River Basin (China Institute of Water Resources and Hydropower Research) open research funds (IWHR-SKL-KF201820, IWHR-SKL-KF201918).

Prof. Ni, Jing Zhao and Genfa Chen developed the CGE model, and collected and analyzed the data, and Prof. Peng organized the paper.

The authors have no conflicts of interest.

1

The State Council. Energy Development Strategic Action Plan (2014–2020) 2014.

2

2 is commonly used for an energy substitution relationship in many models (Adams & Parmenter 2013; Dai et al., 2016; Li et al., 2000; Antimiani et al., 2015). In SinoTERM, the substitution elasticity between other intermediate inputs for each industry is 0.15.

3

Since the location of the hydropower station of the project is confidential, we could not reveal the exact location of the hydropower station.

4

China Input–Output Association (CIOA). Input–output table Available from: http://www.iochina.org.cn/Download/xgxz.html2007 (accessed 11/2015).

5

The closures and data used to create a historical baseline from 2007 to 2016 are explained in detail in Dixon and Rimmer (2002).

6

The data on household consumption, investment, government spending, international exports and imports of the detailed regions and sectors were all taken from China Statistical yearbooks. Even though the yearbooks include some commodity data on international trade, we chose to use more disaggregated data from the United Nation's commodity trade database. These are particularly useful in updating sectors with the most rapid trade growth: for exports, including manufacture sectors, and for imports including metal ores, coal, oil and gas (Dixon and Rimmer, 2002).

7

Data sources: China Statistical Yearbook

9

The World Bank, World Development Indicators. GDP deflator [Data file]. 2012–2017. Retrieved from http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/NY.GDP.DEFL.ZS.

All relevant data are included in the paper or its Supplementary Information.;.

Adams
P. D.
&
Parmenter
B. R.
, (
2013
).
Chapter 9–Computable general equilibrium modeling of environmental issues in Australia: economic impacts of an emissions trading scheme
. In: P. B. Dixon & D. W. Jorgenson, eds.
Handbook of Computable General Equilibrium Modeling
, Vol.
1
. Elsevier B. V., pp.
553
657
.
Adams
P. D.
,
Horridge
M.
&
Wittwer
G.
, (
2003
).
MMRF-GREEN: A Dynamic Multi-Regional Applied General Equilibrium Model of the Australian Economy, Based on the MMR and MONASH Models
.
Centre of Policy Studies/impact Centre Working Papers
.
Antimiani
A.
,
Costantini
V.
&
Paglialunga
E.
, (
2015
).
An Analysis of the Sensitivity of A Dynamic Climate-Economy CGE Model (GDynE) to Empirically Estimated Energy-Related Elasticity Parameters
.
Seeds Working Papers
.
Bakken
T. H.
,
Guri Aase
A.
,
Hagen
D.
,
Sundt
H.
,
Barton
D. N.
&
Lujala
P.
, (
2014
).
Demonstrating a new framework for the comparison of environmental impacts from small- and large-scale hydropower and wind power projects
.
J. Environ. Manag.
140
,
93
101
.
Bhatia
R.
,
Cestti
R.
,
Scatasta
M.
&
Malik
R.
, (
2008
).
Indirect Economic Impacts of Dams: Case Studies From India, Egypt and Brazil
.
Academic Foundation for World Bank
,
New Delhi
.
Bhattacharyya
S. C.
, (
1996
).
Applied general equilibrium models for energy studies: a survey
.
Energy Econ.
18
(
3
),
145
164
. doi.org/10.1016/0140-9883(96)00013-8
Boehlert, B., Strzepek, K. M., Gebretsadik, Y., Swanson, R., McCluskey, A., Neumann, J. E., McFarland, J. & Martinich, J
. (
2016
).
Climate change impacts and greenhouse gas mitigation effects on U.S. hydropower generation
.
Appl. Energy
183
,
1511
1519
.
Brown
P. H.
,
Tullos
D.
,
Tilt
B.
,
Magee
D.
&
Wolf
A. T.
, (
2009
).
Modeling the costs and benefits of dam construction from a multidisciplinary perspective
.
J. Environ. Manag.
90
,
303
311
.
Burniaux
J. M.
&
Truong
T. P.
, (
2002
).
GTAP-E: An Energy–Environmental Version of the GTAP Model
.
GTAP Technical Paper no. 16
,
Purdue University
.
Cestti
R.
&
Malik
R.
, (
2012
).
Impacts of large dams: a global assessment
.
Water Resour. Dev. Mana.
2
,
19
35
.
Cooke
F. M.
,
Nordensvard
J.
,
Saat
G. B.
,
Urban
F.
&
Siciliano
G.
, (
2017
).
The limits of social protection: the case of hydropower dams and indigenous peoples’ land
.
Asia Pac. Policy Stud.
4
(
12
),
1
14
.
Dixon
P.
&
Rimmer
M.
, (
2002
).
Dynamic General Equilibrium Modeling for Forecasting and Policy: A Practical Guide and Documentation of MONASH
.
North-Holland
,
Amsterdam
.
Elokhin
E.
&
Goruleva
L.
, (
1969
).
Economic efficiency of the Volga-Kama dam system
.
Hydrotech. Constr.
3
,
123
127
.
Goldsmith
E.
&
Hildyard
N.
, (
1984
).
The Social and Environmental Effects of Large Dams: Vol. I. Overview, Vol. 2. Cast Studies, Vol. 3. A Review of the Literature
.
Wadebridge Ecological Centre
,
Wadebridge, UK
.
Henderson
J.
,
Rodgers
C.
,
Jones
R.
,
Smith
J.
,
Strzepek
K.
&
Martinich
J.
, (
2013
).
Economic impacts of climate change on water resources of the coterminous United States
.
Mitig. Adapt Strateg. Glob. Change
20
,
135
157
.
Horridge, M. & Pearson, K. (2011). Solution software for CGE modelling. Centre of Policy Studies/IMPACT Centre Working Papers g-214, Victoria University, Centre of Policy Studies/IMPACT Centre.
Horridge
M.
,
Meeraus
A.
,
Pearson
K.
&
Rutherford
T. F.
, (
2013
).
Chapter 20 – solution software for computable general equilibrium modeling
. In: P. B. Dixon & D. W. Jorgenson, eds.
Handbook of Computable General Equilibrium Modeling SET
, Vol.
1A and 1B
. Elsevier B.V., pp.
1331
1381
.
Hu
B.
,
Yang
Z.
,
Wang
H.
,
Sun
X.
,
Bi
N.
&
Li
G.
, (
2009
).
Sedimentation in the Three Gorges Dam and the future trend of Changjiang (Yangtze River) sediment flux to the sea
.
Hydrol. Earth Syst. Sci.
13
,
2253
2264
.
International Energy Agency
. (
2016
).
World Energy Outlook 2016
. IEA, Paris.
Jackson
S.
&
Sleigh
A.
, (
2000
).
Resettlement for China's Three Gorges Dam: socio-economic impact and institutional tensions
.
Communist Post-Communist Stud.
33
,
223
241
.
Lao
C.
, (
2016
).
A study on regional economic impact of hydropower development in Tibet
.
Financ. Minds
1
(
4
),
86
96
.
Lerer
L.
&
Scudder
T.
, (
1999
).
Health impacts of large dams
.
Environ. Impact Assess. Rev.
19
,
113
123
.
Lettenmaier
D. P.
,
Wood
A. W.
,
Palner
R. N.
,
Wood
E. F.
&
Stakhiv
E. Z.
, (
1999
).
Water resources implications of global warming: a U.S. regional perspective
.
Clim. Change
43
,
537
579
.
Li
P.
,
Huang
C.
&
Hsu
S.
, (
2000
).
Energy Substitution in CGE Modeling Using the ‘Technology Bundle’ Approach: The Case of Taiwan
.
Liu
X.
, (
2012
).
China's electric power demand may have a turning point around 2030. China energy news Oct. 22, issue 24
.
Ma
J.
,
Liu
Y.
,
Wang
H.
,
Yan
D.
,
Lv
Y.
&
Yang
Z.
, (
2015
).
Socioeconomic impacts of hydropower development on the Yibin–Chongqing section, upper reaches of the Yangtze River
.
Phys. Chem. Earth Parts A/b/c
89–90
,
73
78
.
Mai, Y., Dixon, P. & Rimmer, M. (2010). CHINAGEM: A Monash-Styled Dynamic CGE Model of China. Centre of Policy Studies/IMPACT Centre Working Papers g-201, Victoria University, Centre of Policy Studies/IMPACT Centre, Melbourne, Australia.
McCallum
W.
, (
2008
).
Before the dam. A Study of Environmental Impacts And Community Rights Associated With the Construction and Operation of the Approved Kirirom III Hydropower Scheme, Sre Ambel District, Southwest Cambodia. American Friends Service Committee and Rivers Coalition in Cambodia. Available from: http://www.afsc.org/sites/afsc.civicactions.net/files/documents/Before%20the%20Dam.pdf.
McDonaldWilmsen
B.
&
Webber
M.
, (
2010
).
Dams and displacement: raising the standards and broadening the research agenda
.
Water Altern.
3
(
2
),
142
161
.
McDougall
R. A.
, (
1993
).
Energy Taxes and Greenhouse Gas Emissions in Australia
.
CoPS/IMPACT Working Papers no. G-104
,
Monash University, Melbourne
.
National Development and Reform Commission
(
2016
).
The 13th Five-Year Plan for National Economic and Social Development of the PRC and 2030 Outlook
.
National Development and Reform Commission of China (NDRC)
(
2010
).
Letter Including Autonomous Domestic Mitigation Actions
.
National Energy Administration
(
2016
).
The 13th Five-Year Plan for Electric Power Development
.
Ortolano, L., Cushing, K. K., Carter, N., May, K. & Watkins, M. (2000). Grand Coulee Dam and the Columbia Basin Project, USA. Case study report prepared as an input to the World Commission on Dams. Cape Town, South Africa
.
Owen
W. F.
, (
1964
).
Land and water use in the Egyptian era
.
Land Econ.
40
(
3
),
277
293
.
Plessis
L. A. D.
&
Viljoen
M. F.
, (
1999
).
Determining the benefits of flood mitigation measures in the lower Orange River: a GIS application
.
Water SA
25
,
205
213
.
Siciliano
G.
,
Urban
F.
,
Kim
S.
&
Lonn
P.
, (
2015
).
Hydropower, social priorities and the rural–urban development divide: the case of large dams in Cambodia
.
Energy Policy
86
(
6
),
273
285
.
Strzepek
K.
,
Yohe
G.
,
Tol
R.
&
Rosegrant
M.
, (
2008
).
The value of the high Aswan dam to the Egyptian economy
.
Ecol. Econ.
66
,
117
126
.
The Chinese Academy of Engineering
. (
2011
).
Research on China's Medium and Long Term (2030, 2050) Energy Development Strategy
.
Science Press
,
Beijing, China
.
United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC)
. (
2015
).
Intended Nationally Determined Contributions (INDCs)
.
Retrieved September 2nd, 2015, from: http://unfccc.int/focus/indc_portal/items/8766.php.
Urban
F.
,
Mohan
G.
&
Cook
S.
, (
2013
).
China as a new shaper of international development: the environmental implications
.
Environ. Dev. Sustain.
15
(
2
),
257
263
.
WCD
. (
2000
).
Dams and Development: A new Framework for Decision Making
.
Earthscan Publications Ltd.
,
London and Sterling, VA
,
The report of the World Commission on Dams
.
Wittwer
G.
&
Horridge
M.
, (
2008
).
A multi-regional representation of China's agricultural sectors
.
China Agr. Econ. Rev.
1
,
420
434
.
Wittwer
G.
&
Horridge
M.
, (
2010
).
Bringing regional detail to a CGE model using census data
.
Spat. Econ. Anal.
5
,
229
255
.
Wittwer
G.
,
Vere
D.
,
Jones
R.
&
Griffith
G.
, (
2005
).
Dynamic general equilibrium analysis of improved weed management in Australia's winter cropping systems
.
Aust. J. Agr. Resour. Econ.
49
,
363
377
.
World Bank
(
2004
).
Summary Overview. Lao PDR Country Economic Memorandum: Realizing the Development Potential of Lao PDR
.
East Asia and Pacific Region, Word Bank
,
Washington, DC
.
Xia, B., Qiang, M., Jiang, H., Wen, Q., An, N. & Zhang, D
. (
2020
).
Phase-based externality analysis for large hydropower projects
.
Environ. Impact Assess. Rev.
80
(
1
),
106332.1
106332.12
.
Yao
Y.
,
Wang
Q.
,
Li
J.
,
Shen
X.
&
Kong
Y.
, (
2013
).
Seismic hazard assessment of the Three Gorges Project
.
Geod. Geodyn.
4
,
53
60
.
Zou, C., Xiong, B., Xue, H., Zheng, D., Ge, Zh, Wang, Y., Jiang, L., Pan, S. & Wu, S
. (
2021
).
The role of new energy in carbon neutral
.
Petroleum Explor. Dev.
48
(
2
),
480
491
.
This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution Licence (CC BY 4.0), which permits copying, adaptation and redistribution, provided the original work is properly cited (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

Supplementary data