Levying a water resources tax policy which is called ‘fee to tax’ is a regulation formulated by China to restrain and alleviate water poverty. To test the effect of the water resources ‘fee to tax’, this research employs a multistage dynamic difference-in-differences (DID) model to explore whether the implementation of the policy can help alleviate water poverty based on panel data from 2009 to 2019. The results indicate the water poverty in western China is significantly more serious than in other regions and the implementation of the water resources tax policy significantly alleviates water poverty (the sign of the policy is positive and significant at the 1% level) in China. Additionally, the mechanism effects suggest that the policy can effectively restrain water poverty by reducing groundwater exploitation and optimizing the water utilization structure. In terms of spatial heterogeneity, the effect of the water resources tax policy on alleviating water poverty is stronger in central and eastern regions than in western regions. The conclusions of this study may, to some degree, serve as a basis to scientifically guide the implementation of China's water resources ‘fee to tax’ policy and, thus, effectively improve the level of water resources management.

  • There is temporal and spatial heterogeneity of ‘water poverty’ across China.

  • DID model is applied to test the effect of the policy on water poverty.

  • The ‘fee to tax’ policy has significantly restrained water poverty.

  • The ‘fee to tax’ policy effect is stronger in central and eastern regions than in western regions.

  • Policies towards water resources management and water poverty alleviation are proposed.

Graphical Abstract

Graphical Abstract

Since many developing countries are affected by water scarcity and climate crises are expected to worsen this issue, it is crucial to understand how increasing threats to water availability might affect future progress in human development and economic take-off (Moshtagh & Mohsenpour 2020; Prabha et al. 2020). Accordingly, water management has become a priority for policy-makers, and a key component of water management strategies is alleviating water poverty (Fito & Van Hulle 2021). Water poverty is a concept that transcends water scarcity and is multidimensional, focusing specifically on the social and economic aspects of water resource management (Yoon et al. 2021). Indeed, among the various tools proposed to address water poverty, the use of the water poverty index (WPI) is noteworthy and holistic (Koirala et al. 2020). The WPI is a multidimensional tool that includes the assessment of water stress situations based on five components: resources, assessment, capacity, environment, and use. Although WPI requires multiple datasets for its construction, it is an improvement over previous indices because it links the estimates of water availability with socio-economic dimensions (Thakur et al. 2017). Recent endeavors to use the WPI have concentrated on regional comparisons between countries, states or sub-districts and on factors influencing water poverty (Sullivan et al. 2006; Jemmali 2017).

As water poverty has worsened, relevant departments of the country must devote close attention to and focus on the treatment of water resources, and the collection of water resource fees and taxes has gradually developed into a popular research topic (Tian et al. 2021). The water resources tax is classified as a resource tax, which is also known as a green tax. Early scholars, such as Pigou, advocated taxing natural resources according to the degree of destruction, which laid the theoretical foundation of resource tax collection (Jacobs & Mooij 2015). Following those studies, research about the theory of resource tax and its scope were studied in-depth. The introduction of a water resource tax policy has been effectively verified in Germany, Great Britain and other European countries to reduce water poverty and promote the water resource management process (Thomas & Zaporozhets 2017). Based on the available water resource taxes and water poverty situation, China's central government launched a formal national water resource ‘fee to tax’ policy in Hebei Province in 2016. In November 2017, taxes were reformed according to the success in Hebei Province. To expand the scope of the water resources tax reform areas, the ‘1 + 9’ pilot pattern was formed in China (Figure 1). In this context, it is essential to estimate how the water resource ‘fee to tax’ policy can restrain water poverty.
Figure 1

Province distribution of China's water resource tax pilot policy in 2016 and 2017.

Figure 1

Province distribution of China's water resource tax pilot policy in 2016 and 2017.

Close modal

Theoretically, the water resources tax policy is meant to contribute to water conservation in the following ways. First, since a water resources tax will increase the tax burden on each entity's water consumption, it can stimulate entities to adopt new water-conserving technologies, which has long been seen as a powerful approach to conserve water and change the water utilization pattern in high-consumption fields (Benyezza et al. 2021). Second, taxation's mandatory nature improves its efficiency, increases tax consciousness, and causes each unity to recognize the scarcity of water resources via the publicity of the water situation and tax knowledge by relevant departments, ultimately increasing consumer awareness of sustainable water consumption (Gómez-Llanos et al. 2020). Lastly, the levied tax's revenue can be invested in water resource protection and water body restoration via the creation of special accounts and using the special tax fund supply to further protect water resources and conserve water. In contrast, several studies argue that the water resources tax increases the taxpayer burden and is not conducive to water conservation (Kilimani et al. 2015). Literature shows that the existing research results remain controversial. However, knowledge gaps exist about the extent to which the water resources policy can alleviate water poverty, and the theoretical mechanism remains unclear and requires quantification.

Difference in differences (DID) is a commonly used quasi-experimental approach to evaluate the causal effects of specific public policies. Since the implementation of a public policy is usually not influenced by the subject, the policy can be regarded as an exogenous ‘intervention’ to the subject; therefore, the implementation of the policy can also be recognized as a quasi-experiment (Salinas & Solé-Ollé 2018). The fundamental purpose of the DID approach is to comprehensively investigate the differences amongst the differences both with and without and before and after the enforcement of certain policies (Ashenfelter 1978). The DID model estimates the net effect of policy implementation by comparing the differences in dependent variables between the experimental group and the control group before and after the implementation of such policies (Hu et al. 2022). In recent years, increasing numbers of scholars have applied the DID model to conduct causal analysis of public policy effects, such as Moser & Voena (2012), Chagas et al. (2016), and Kosfeld et al. (2021). China's implementation of the water resources ‘fee to tax’ policy provides a fitting case for the scientific evaluation of water poverty's net effect. Therefore, on the basis of the multistage DID model, this study intends to explore three key issues: (1) Does nationwide water poverty exhibit any spatial and temporal characteristics? To what degree does the water resource ‘fee to tax’ policy affect water poverty? (2) What are the mechanisms by which the water resources tax policy affects water poverty? (3) What are the regional differences in and results of heterogeneity analysis of the water resources tax policy?

Water scarcity and uneven spatial distribution of water resources have become two of the major obstacles to sustainable economic development in China. Additionally, excessive extraction of groundwater resources for irrigation to meet the needs of a growing population and ensure food security has largely exacerbated water poverty (Westmore 2018). Therefore, in China's distinctive political system, the central government has adopted a ‘two-handed’ approach to alleviating water poverty that includes a combination of strong central regulation and infrastructure development and the adoption of market principles (Svensson et al. 2021). Economic leverage is the most efficient market tool. Accordingly, following the promulgation of the Water Law of the People's Republic of China in 1988, the water resource fee began to be collected from all citizens. Due to low overall water prices, the ambiguous responsibilities of relevant sectors, and the nonstandard utilization of water resource fees, the current policy of collecting and paying water resource fees can no longer meet national development needs. China is currently reforming the 32-year-old water resources fee policy and plans to replace a more lenient water fee with a stricter water tax; thus, the work of the ‘water resources fee to tax reform’ was implemented.

In July 2016, the Ministry of Water Resources (MWR) of China issued the ‘water resources tax policy’ in Hebei Province to increase water use efficiency and alleviate water poverty. Since the water resource tax reform was implemented, unreasonable water demand has been effectively reduced in Hebei Province, which proves that the water resource tax policy has the basis and conditions to expand. Therefore, in November 2017, the scope of the tax reform was expanded, and the ‘1 + 9’ pilot pattern was formed. These nine provinces are in the eastern (Beijing, Tianjin, and Shandong), central (Henan and Shanxi) and western regions (Inner Mongolia, Ningxia, Sichuan, and Shaanxi) (Figure 1) of China. These representative regions encompass economically developed areas and underdeveloped areas, and the regions show large differences in water resource endowments, major grain-producing areas and nonmajor grain-producing areas. The Chinese government regards the water resources tax policy as a crucial economic incentive to decrease water consumption. However, has the ‘fee to tax’ policy truly alleviated water poverty? If so, to what extent? What are the mechanisms and heterogeneous differences in the effects of water poverty? This study will address these issues.

Water resources tax policy and water poverty

Price mechanisms are an important tool and means of market regulation (Ergunova et al. 2018). By charging money for resources, we can effectively solve the problem of resource externality, fully protect resources, and promote rational resource utilization (Hotelling 1931; Eisenack et al. 2012; Ing 2020). Levying the water resource tax increases the cost of water utilization and, thus, affects the water intake and use behavior of enterprises and the public (Tian et al. 2021). Therefore, the implementation of the policy of water resources tax will help enterprises and the public develop water-conserving awareness, reduce water consumption, promote the sustainable utilization of water resources, and lastly, reduce water poverty. Based on the above analysis, the first theoretical hypothesis is proposed:

Hypothesis 1: The water resources tax policy can effectively reduce water poverty.

The intermediate mechanism of the water resources tax policy to alleviate water poverty

Water resource tax policy may reduce water poverty via several channels. First, groundwater extraction should be controlled. Tax policy can promote the management of groundwater resources (Lorphensri et al. 2011; Wang et al. 2020). The water resources tax policy brings groundwater into the scope of taxation. More importantly, the tax standard for groundwater water resources is higher than that of surface water when the same amount of water is used. Therefore, the reform of the water resource tax increases the tax burden between groundwater and surface water and overexploited and underexploited areas, which is conducive to protecting water resources and alleviating water poverty.

Second, the water use structure should be optimized. Using the difference of tax burden, the water resources tax enables enterprises to adjust water use structures, reduce the proportion of groundwater use and promote the sustainable utilization of water resources. In addition, the proportion of agricultural and industrial water in China is excessive. The water quota specified in several provinces is converted according to the effective utilization coefficient of farmland irrigation water, which is intended to encourage farmers to conserve water. For industrial water, the pilot policy imposes a higher standard on general industrial water than domestic water and agricultural water and doubles the water resource tax for water use exceeding the quota. The objective is to optimize the structure of water use and improve the efficiency of industrial water use, resulting in the improvement in water poverty conditions (Wei et al. 2018). Based on the above analysis, the second theoretical hypothesis is proposed:

Hypothesis 2: The water resources tax policy can reduce water poverty by controlling groundwater extraction and optimizing the structure of water use.

Heterogeneous effects of the water resources tax policy on water poverty

The policy may have clear regional differences in the alleviation level of water poverty. The water poverty situation in the western region of China is more severe than that in the central and eastern regions, where economic and social development is being confronted with a bottleneck caused by water shortages. In addition, the western region is located in an arid zone that has low annual precipitation, agricultural water use efficiency, and high levels of waste. Moreover, the taxes in the western region are generally lower than that in the central and eastern regions, which reflects the government's emphasis on using tax leverage to encourage industries to increase water utilization efficiency (Gao & Yin 2016). Therefore, compared with the western region, the implementation of the water resources tax policy may more effectively reduce water poverty in the central and eastern regions. Based on the above analysis, the third theoretical hypothesis of this study is proposed:

Hypothesis 3: The water resources tax policy will more strongly mitigate water poverty in the eastern and central regions than in the western region.

Based on the research framework, a flowchart of the method used in this paper was designed, as shown in Figure 2.
Figure 2

Research flowchart of the water resource tax pilot policy on alleviating water poverty.

Figure 2

Research flowchart of the water resource tax pilot policy on alleviating water poverty.

Close modal

Water poverty measurement

Composition of the water poverty index (WPI)

The WPI method is used to describe the water poverty situation in 31 provinces (municipalities) in China. The WPI encompasses five key dimensions, namely, resources, access, capacity, use and environment. Each component corresponds to different indicators. Table 1 shows the indicators under each component.

Table 1

List of indicators applied in the calculation of the water poverty index (WPI)

ComponentsResourceUseAccessCapacityEnvironment
Indicators R1: Total water resources U1: Total agricultural water use A1: Land irrigation area C1: Fiscal self-sufficiency rate E2: Daily urban sewage treatment capacity 
R2: The water resource of per capita U2: Total industrial water use A2: Urban water penetration rate C2: Local scientific and technological financial support E2: Park green area per capita 
R3: Precipitation in each province (municipalities) U3: Gross domestic water consumption A3: Comprehensive production capacity of water supply C3: Average number of students in colleges and universities per E3: Amount of agricultural fertilizer 
 U4: Total ecological water use  C4: Engel coefficient E4: Area for waterlogging prevention and soil erosion control 
ComponentsResourceUseAccessCapacityEnvironment
Indicators R1: Total water resources U1: Total agricultural water use A1: Land irrigation area C1: Fiscal self-sufficiency rate E2: Daily urban sewage treatment capacity 
R2: The water resource of per capita U2: Total industrial water use A2: Urban water penetration rate C2: Local scientific and technological financial support E2: Park green area per capita 
R3: Precipitation in each province (municipalities) U3: Gross domestic water consumption A3: Comprehensive production capacity of water supply C3: Average number of students in colleges and universities per E3: Amount of agricultural fertilizer 
 U4: Total ecological water use  C4: Engel coefficient E4: Area for waterlogging prevention and soil erosion control 

Resource: Resource is broadly defined as the total amount of available water in a particular country or region. Here, we use the number of total water resources (R1), the water resources per capita (R2), and precipitation in each province (municipalities) (R3) as three indicators to capture the resource component.

Use: The use dimension typically encompasses the quantity of water used by different water use sectors. In China's water use statistics, water use is usually divided into four categories: agriculture, industry, life, and ecology. Therefore, we select the following four indicators to represent the use components: total agricultural water use (U1), total industrial water use (U2), gross domestic water consumption (U3) and total ecological water use (U4).

Access: Access to sufficient water is essential for production and life. In this study, crop irrigation water, safe domestic water and maximum water supply are considered, and the cultivated land irrigation area (A1), urban water penetration rate (A2) and comprehensive production capacity of water supply (A3) are selected for measurement.

Capacity: Capacity represents the purchasing and management power of water. The financial self-sufficiency rate (C1), local scientific and technological financial support (C2), average number of college students per 100,000 people (C3) and Engel coefficient (C4) are selected as the indicators of capacity. C1 refers to the ratio of local fiscal revenues to local fiscal expenditures, C2 denotes the proportion of local science and technology expenditure in total financial expenditure, C3 represents the education level of the population, and C4 reflects the living standard of the citizens of the province (city), which is used to measure citizens’ ability to buy safe water.

Environment: The environmental component attempts to evaluate the degree of environmental integrity by analyzing the ecological or human factors that may affect the quantity or quality of water in the living environment. Daily urban sewage treatment capacity (E1), park green area per capita (E2), amount of agricultural fertilizer (E3) and area for waterlogging prevention and soil erosion control (E4) are selected as indicators of the environment.

Assignment of weights for each indicator

To avoid the arbitrariness of a subjective weighting method, the entropy value method is implemented (Song et al. 2017; Wu et al. 2021). The following steps are applied to decide the weights of each indicator.

Step 1: Decision Matrix

Suppose that there are m evaluation indices and n evaluated objects. An evaluation matrix is then formed based on the information of each evaluated object's index:
(1)
where i = 1, 2, …, m; j = 1, 2, …, n; and xij represents the value of index i.

Step 2: Standardization

The improved min-max normalisation method is used to standardize the data. Compared with existing studies (Heidecke 2006; Zhang et al. 2015), the advantage of this method is that boundary values of 0 and 1 are avoided while standardizing the data. In addition, this study actively addresses indicators with lower WPI values and higher degrees of water poverty. This study also obtains indicators with lower WPI values corresponding to more severe degrees of water poverty. The standardized formula is as follows:
(2)

Step 3: Probability and Entropy

Subsequently, pij is calculated using Equation (3). The entropy of the WPI is defined based on Equation (4):
(3)
(4)

When pij = 0, pij⋅lnpij = 0. In addition, Ei lies in the [0, 1] domain.

Step 4: Entropy Weights

Therefore, the weight of each index is expressed as follows:
(5)

Calculation of the water poverty index (WPI)

This study adopts the weighted arithmetic mean method (El-Gafy 2018) to determine the WPI. The computational formula is presented below:
(6)
where WPIj is the water poverty index value of a specific region. The smaller the value is, the worse the local water resources are. In addition, wi indicates the weight of each index via the entropy value method; and yij is the normalized value obtained using the improved min-max normalisation method.

Econometric model

DID model

This research uses the multistage DID model to identify the impact of the water resources tax policy on water poverty and its mechanism. We designated the area where the policy was implemented as the experimental group and the remaining provinces (municipalities) as the control group. The following econometric model is established:
(7)
where i indicates the province (municipality), t shows the year, and WPIit represents the water poverty of province (municipality) i in year t. Additionally, Treatit is a dummy variable that denotes the main independent variable (pilot water resources tax policy). Its value is 1 if province (municipality) i is a pilot area in year t and 0 otherwise. Xit are the control variables at the provincial level. μi refers to the time fixed effect. λt represents the province fixed effect. Lastly, εit is a random perturbation term. In Equation (7), the coefficient of interest is β1, and if its estimated value is greater than 0, then the policy reduces water poverty in the pilot areas more than the other areas.

Selection of related variables

The WPI is recognized as the dependent variable, which is calculated by the entropy weight method. The core independent variable is the water resources tax policy, which is presented by a dummy variable. That is, if province (municipality) i is a pilot area in year t, the value is 1; otherwise, the value is 0. In the model, we also need to control other variables that affect water poverty, including the economic development level (PGDP), water consumption per capita (PWC), population size (POP), urbanization rate (URBAN), per-acre water consumption of arable land (AGRI), water consumption per 10,000 yuan of industrial added value (INDU), and fixed effects of time and provinces (municipalities).

Data sources and descriptions

The final sample of this article includes 341 observations (31 provinces from 2009 to 2019) based on data from the ‘China Statistical Yearbook’, ‘China Rural Statistical Yearbook’, ‘China Environmental Statistics Yearbook’, ‘China Water Conservancy Statistical Yearbook’, ‘China Water Resources Bulletin’ and National Bureau of Statistics of China. Table 2 displays the definitions and descriptive statistics for all variables. All the data were analyzed using Stata 15.

Table 2

Variable definitions and descriptive statistics

VariablesDefinitionsMeanSDMinMax
Dependent variable 
WPI Water poverty index 0.207 0.081 0.078 0.457 
Independent variable 
Treat Province i is a water policy pilot area in year t and takes the value 1, otherwise it is 0     
Control variables 
PGDP The natural logarithm of gross regional product per capita 10.314 0.524 8.904 11.736 
AGRI The natural logarithm of water consumption per mu of cultivated land under solid irrigation 5.993 0.486 5.690 9.433 
POP The natural logarithm of population size 8.119 0.846 5.690 9.433 
PWC The natural logarithm of water consumption per capita 6.063 0.579 5.082 7.885 
URBAN Urbanization rate 55.478 13.799 22.222 94.152 
INDU The natural logarithm of water consumption per 10,000 yuan of industrial added value 3.987 0.759 2.051 6.009 
VariablesDefinitionsMeanSDMinMax
Dependent variable 
WPI Water poverty index 0.207 0.081 0.078 0.457 
Independent variable 
Treat Province i is a water policy pilot area in year t and takes the value 1, otherwise it is 0     
Control variables 
PGDP The natural logarithm of gross regional product per capita 10.314 0.524 8.904 11.736 
AGRI The natural logarithm of water consumption per mu of cultivated land under solid irrigation 5.993 0.486 5.690 9.433 
POP The natural logarithm of population size 8.119 0.846 5.690 9.433 
PWC The natural logarithm of water consumption per capita 6.063 0.579 5.082 7.885 
URBAN Urbanization rate 55.478 13.799 22.222 94.152 
INDU The natural logarithm of water consumption per 10,000 yuan of industrial added value 3.987 0.759 2.051 6.009 

Calculation results of WPI

Temporal and spatial variation of WPI

The temporal–spatial variation in WPI is shown in Figure 3. In general, the WPI trended upwards from 2009 to 2019, indicating that the water poverty level had decreased each year. Specifically, water poverty reveals regional heterogeneity. First, the western region has poor water resource endowment. The water poverty values in the western region are lower than in most parts of China. Second, water poverty varies among provinces (municipalities) in the central region. Since 2009, water poverty in Henan and Hubei has been significantly alleviated, while provinces such as Jilin continue to show more severe water poverty. Third, the eastern region shows the greatest changes in water poverty. The water resources poverty in eastern regions such as Hebei, Shandong and Beijing has been significantly improved, especially since the water resources tax policy was implemented in 2016.
Figure 3

Spatial and temporal variation of water poverty (WPI) in China from 2009 to 2019.

Figure 3

Spatial and temporal variation of water poverty (WPI) in China from 2009 to 2019.

Close modal

Changes in the WPI before and after water resources tax policy implementation

Tables 3 and 4 indicates the average value of water poverty in the pilot and non-pilot areas from 2009 to 2019 and shows the changing trend of water poverty by comparing the conditions before and after policy implementation. Before the implementation of the water rights trading pilot policy, the average water poverty value in most pilot areas was lower than the average in the non-pilot areas. After the policy was implemented, the water poverty value in the pilot areas increased significantly, and the water poverty value in non-pilot areas decreased. Moreover, the gap between the pilot provinces and the national average gradually narrowed. This finding demonstrates that compared with non-pilot areas, the implementation of the water resources tax pilot policy has significantly alleviated water poverty in the pilot areas. However, further conclusions must be obtained using an econometric model.

Table 3

The differences of water poverty index (WPI) between the first pilot (Hebei province) and non-pilot regions from 2009 to 2019

Pilot areasBefore policy implementation
After the policy is implemented
2009201020112012201320142015mean2016201720182019mean
Hebei Province 0.178 0.174 0.19 0.189 0.183 0.178 0.176 0.181 0.176 0.172 0.189 0.189 0.182 
Non-pilot areas 0.219 0.227 0.221 0.229 0.221 0.222 0.232 0.224 0.224 0.216 0.213 0.215 0.217 
All 0.202 0.209 0.209 0.215 0.206 0.206 0.214 0.209 0.207 0.203 0.202 0.201 0.203 
Pilot areasBefore policy implementation
After the policy is implemented
2009201020112012201320142015mean2016201720182019mean
Hebei Province 0.178 0.174 0.19 0.189 0.183 0.178 0.176 0.181 0.176 0.172 0.189 0.189 0.182 
Non-pilot areas 0.219 0.227 0.221 0.229 0.221 0.222 0.232 0.224 0.224 0.216 0.213 0.215 0.217 
All 0.202 0.209 0.209 0.215 0.206 0.206 0.214 0.209 0.207 0.203 0.202 0.201 0.203 
Table 4

The differences of water poverty index (WPI) between the second batch of pilot and non-pilot regions from 2009 to 2019

Pilot areasBefore policy implementation
After the policy is implemented
20092010201120122013201420152016mean201720182019mean
The second batch of pilot regions 0.166 0.169 0.184 0.184 0.176 0.172 0.177 0.170 0.175 0.176 0.179 0.170 0.175 
Non-pilot areas 0.219 0.227 0.221 0.229 0.221 0.222 0.232 0.224 0.224 0.216 0.213 0.215 0.215 
All 0.202 0.209 0.209 0.215 0.206 0.206 0.214 0.207 0.209 0.203 0.202 0.201 0.202 
Pilot areasBefore policy implementation
After the policy is implemented
20092010201120122013201420152016mean201720182019mean
The second batch of pilot regions 0.166 0.169 0.184 0.184 0.176 0.172 0.177 0.170 0.175 0.176 0.179 0.170 0.175 
Non-pilot areas 0.219 0.227 0.221 0.229 0.221 0.222 0.232 0.224 0.224 0.216 0.213 0.215 0.215 
All 0.202 0.209 0.209 0.215 0.206 0.206 0.214 0.207 0.209 0.203 0.202 0.201 0.202 

Empirical analysis of the effect of water resource tax policy on water poverty

Baseline regression results of the water resource tax policy on water poverty

The results in Table 5 imply that the coefficient sign of the variable ‘Treat’ (estimated quantity of the water resource tax policy) is positive and significant at the 1% level, which indicates that the water resources tax policy can effectively mitigate water poverty. The results for the coefficient of Treat show that after policy implementation, the water poverty value of the pilot provinces (municipalities) increases by an average of 0.9 percentage points compared with the non-pilot provinces (municipalities), which validates Hypothesis 1.

Table 5

Baseline regression results of water resource tax pilot policy on water poverty

Independent variableDependent variable: WPI
(1)(2)
Treat 0.009***b 0.009*** 
 (0.003) (0.003) 
PGDPa  0.100*** 
  (0.024) 
AGRI  −0.037*** 
  (0.010) 
POP  0.069** 
  (0.032) 
PWC  0.039** 
  (0.016) 
URBAN  0.001* 
  (0.001) 
INDU  −0.002 
  (0.006) 
Constant 0.206*** −1.448*** 
 (0.001) (0.272) 
Province_FE Yes Yes 
Year_FE Yes Yes 
341 341 
R2 0.978 0.983 
Independent variableDependent variable: WPI
(1)(2)
Treat 0.009***b 0.009*** 
 (0.003) (0.003) 
PGDPa  0.100*** 
  (0.024) 
AGRI  −0.037*** 
  (0.010) 
POP  0.069** 
  (0.032) 
PWC  0.039** 
  (0.016) 
URBAN  0.001* 
  (0.001) 
INDU  −0.002 
  (0.006) 
Constant 0.206*** −1.448*** 
 (0.001) (0.272) 
Province_FE Yes Yes 
Year_FE Yes Yes 
341 341 
R2 0.978 0.983 

aPGDP (the natural logarithm of gross regional product per capita); AGRI (the natural logarithm of water consumption per mu of cultivated land under solid irrigation); POP (the natural logarithm of total population); PWC (the natural logarithm of per capita water consumption); URBAN (urbanization rate); INDU (the natural logarithm of water consumption per 10,000 yuan of industrial added value).

bThe standard errors adjusted by province-year clustering are in brackets; ***, ** and * indicate significance at the levels of 1, 5 and 10%, respectively.

The results of the control variables show that the economic development level, population size, per capita water consumption and urbanization rate positively impact water poverty, with significant differences at the levels of 1, 5, and 10%, respectively. Specifically, regions with higher levels of economic development are more capable of improving water poverty via investment in capital and technology. The higher the per capita water consumption in a certain area is, the better the water resource endowment in the area and the more conducive the policies are to eliminate water poverty. A higher urbanization rate results in improved protection of resources and contributes to the reduction of water poverty. In addition, the per-acre water consumption of arable land negatively impacts water poverty, with significant differences at the 1% level. The higher the per-acre water consumption of arable land in a certain area, the lower the efficiency of that area's agricultural water use, and ultimately, the higher the water poverty. Lastly, although the impact of the water consumption per 10,000 yuan of industrial added value on water poverty is negative, the value is insignificant, indicating that it cannot notably affect water poverty.

Robustness analysis: parallel trend test

In the DID model, there should be no significant differences in the severity of water poverty between the experimental and control groups before the implementation of this policy. Therefore, conducting the following parallel trend test is necessary.

The event analysis method is used to set the following measurement model:
(8)
where W represents the dummy variable of the water resources tax policy pilot event. Assuming that the year of province i pilot water resources tax policy is li and t is the year, k = t-li is defined. When k ≤ 3, Witk = 1; otherwise it is 0. We use k = −1 as the benchmark period, and k = −1 represents the year prior to the implementation of the water resources tax's pilot policy. Therefore, there is no dummy variable W-1 in Model 8. In addition, the setting of other variables in Model (8) is consistent with reference Model (7). The parameter βk reflects the impact of the water resources tax policy on water poverty in the pilot group of provinces (municipalities) before and after the policy implementation.
If k < −1 and the parameter βk fails to reject the original hypothesis equal to 0, then the common trend hypothesis is true. According to the results shown in Figure 4, before the policy was implemented, the estimated value of parameter βk was not significantly different from zero, which proves that the progressive double difference method meets the common trend hypothesis. After the implementation of the water resources tax policy, the estimated value of parameter βk is always significantly positive, which demonstrates that the policy weakens water poverty. The curve generally implies an upwards trend, which demonstrates that the policy can continually alleviate water poverty.
Figure 4

Parallel trend test chart: comparative analysis of changes in water poverty before and after the implementation of water resource tax pilot policy.

Figure 4

Parallel trend test chart: comparative analysis of changes in water poverty before and after the implementation of water resource tax pilot policy.

Close modal

Robustness analysis: placebo test

To further verify the robustness of the above results, individuals were randomly assigned to the treatment group to generate ‘pseudo policy dummy variables’ for the placebo regression test. The goal is to randomly assign individuals to each treatment group. Next, we randomly select a time for each treatment group as its policy time point. Lastly, the ‘pseudo policy dummy variable’ treatitfalse is created. Model 9 is thus applied:
(9)
The process was repeated 500 and 1,000 times, and the p-value distributions of ‘pseudo policy dummy variables’ were generated. Figure 5 displays the results of the placebo test. Specifically, the time span of this study's data is 2009–2019, with 10 provinces in the processing group and 21 provinces in the control group. Therefore, we randomly selected 10 of the 31 provinces as the ‘pseudo processing group’. These 10 provinces are assumed to have implemented the water resources tax policy, and other provinces are used as the control group. Then, one year is randomly selected as the policy time point (‘pseudo policy time’) for these 10 ‘pseudo treatment groups’ one by one for multistage regression, and the process is repeated 500 and 1,000 times. Figure 5 shows that the p-value of most estimates is greater than 0.1 (insignificant at the 10% level), which proves that the mitigation effect of the water resources tax policy on water poverty is not affected by the missing variables. Therefore, the regression conclusion is stable.
Figure 5

Placebo test: simulation results of random pilot provinces and pilot time ((a) 500 times; (b) 1,000 times).

Figure 5

Placebo test: simulation results of random pilot provinces and pilot time ((a) 500 times; (b) 1,000 times).

Close modal

Mechanism analysis of water resource tax policy for alleviating water poverty

The mechanism of the water resource tax policy on water poverty are discussed from the perspectives of groundwater exploitation and water use structure. To this end, the following measurement model is constructed:
(10)
(11)
(12)

Model (10) is used to test the impact of the water resources tax policy on water poverty. If the coefficient α1 is significant, Model (11) can be used to test the influence of the independent variable (Treat) on the intermediate variable (D). If the coefficient β1 is significant, Model (12) is used to include both the independent variable (Treat) and intermediate variable (D) for analysis. A significant coefficient γ2 and insignificant γ1 indicate a complete intermediary effect. However, a significant coefficient γ2 and the coefficient γ1 indicate a partial mediating effect. An insignificant coefficient γ2 denotes an untenable mediating effect.

Table 6 reveals how the policy affects water poverty under the action of the three mechanism variables. The mechanism of the groundwater supply in Column 1 explores the independent variable (Treat) on the dependent variable, and the estimated coefficient is 0.009, which is significant at the 1% level. Column 2 in Table 6 displays the impact of the independent variable (Treat) on the intermediate variable (Supply). The coefficient is significantly negative at the 1% level, indicating that the implementation of the policy reduces the exploitation of groundwater. In Column 3, the estimated coefficients of the intermediate variable (Supply) and independent variable (Treat) are significant at the levels of 1 and 5%, respectively. The decrease in the significance level of the independent variable (Treat) proves that groundwater exploitation plays a partial intermediary role between the water resources tax policy and water poverty. Similarly, the mechanism of the water use structure is shown in Columns (4)–(9), where (4)–(6) represent the water use structure of different water sources and (7)-(9) represent the water use structure of different water use departments. Both significance levels of the independent variable (Treat) decreased, which indicates that the water use structure plays a partial intermediary role and that the mitigation effect of the water resources tax policy on water poverty increases as the water structure is optimized. Based on the above regression results, Hypothesis 2 is verified.

Table 6

Mechanism analysis of water resource tax pilot policy

Independent variableMechanism 1
Mechanism 2
Mechanism 3
(1) WPI(2) SUPPLY(3) WPI(4) WPI(5) WSS(6) WPI(7) WPI(8) IWS(9) WPI
Treat 0.009***b (0.003) −6.948*** (1.608) 0.006** (0.003)       
SUPPLYa   −0.000*** (0.000)       
Treat    0.009*** (0.003) 0.038*** (0.007) 0.008** (0.003)    
WSS      0.047* (0.028)    
Treat       0.009*** (0.003) −0.037*** (0.007) 0.007** (0.003) 
IWS         −0.061** (0.027) 
PGDP 0.100*** (0.024) 17.162 (10.595) 0.108*** (0.024) 0.100*** (0.024) −0.169*** (0.049) 0.108*** (0.024) 0.100*** (0.024) 0.179** (0.070) 0.111*** (0.023) 
AGRI −0.037*** (0.010) −9.290** (4.090) −0.041*** (0.010) −0.037*** (0.010) 0.031* (0.018) −0.039*** (0.010) −0.037*** (0.010) 0.042 (0.028) −0.035*** (0.010) 
POP 0.069** (0.032) 24.561 (15.147) 0.080*** (0.031) 0.069** (0.032) −0.026 (0.049) 0.070** (0.031) 0.069** (0.032) −0.138 (0.100) 0.061* (0.031) 
PWC 0.039** (0.016) 32.505*** (8.066) 0.053*** (0.016) 0.039** (0.016) 0.070** (0.031) 0.036** (0.016) 0.039** (0.016) −0.139*** (0.043) 0.031* (0.016) 
URBAN 0.001* (0.001) −0.513* (0.269) 0.001 (0.001) 0.001* (0.001) 0.000 (0.001) 0.001* (0.001) 0.001* (0.001) 0.003* (0.002) 0.001** (0.001) 
INDU −0.002 (0.006) −2.860 (2.558) −0.003 (0.006) −0.002 (0.006) −0.018* (0.010) −0.001 (0.006) −0.002 (0.006) 0.052*** (0.018) 0.002 (0.006) 
_cons −1.448*** (0.272) −442.375*** (170.399) −1.641*** (0.267) −1.448*** (0.272) 2.181*** (0.542) −1.551*** (0.276) −1.448*** (0.272) 0.320 (0.664) −1.429*** (0.268) 
Province_FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 
Year_FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 
341 341 341 341 341 341 341 341 341 
Adj_R2 0.983 0.990 0.983 0.983 0.993 0.984 0.983 0.962 0.984 
Independent variableMechanism 1
Mechanism 2
Mechanism 3
(1) WPI(2) SUPPLY(3) WPI(4) WPI(5) WSS(6) WPI(7) WPI(8) IWS(9) WPI
Treat 0.009***b (0.003) −6.948*** (1.608) 0.006** (0.003)       
SUPPLYa   −0.000*** (0.000)       
Treat    0.009*** (0.003) 0.038*** (0.007) 0.008** (0.003)    
WSS      0.047* (0.028)    
Treat       0.009*** (0.003) −0.037*** (0.007) 0.007** (0.003) 
IWS         −0.061** (0.027) 
PGDP 0.100*** (0.024) 17.162 (10.595) 0.108*** (0.024) 0.100*** (0.024) −0.169*** (0.049) 0.108*** (0.024) 0.100*** (0.024) 0.179** (0.070) 0.111*** (0.023) 
AGRI −0.037*** (0.010) −9.290** (4.090) −0.041*** (0.010) −0.037*** (0.010) 0.031* (0.018) −0.039*** (0.010) −0.037*** (0.010) 0.042 (0.028) −0.035*** (0.010) 
POP 0.069** (0.032) 24.561 (15.147) 0.080*** (0.031) 0.069** (0.032) −0.026 (0.049) 0.070** (0.031) 0.069** (0.032) −0.138 (0.100) 0.061* (0.031) 
PWC 0.039** (0.016) 32.505*** (8.066) 0.053*** (0.016) 0.039** (0.016) 0.070** (0.031) 0.036** (0.016) 0.039** (0.016) −0.139*** (0.043) 0.031* (0.016) 
URBAN 0.001* (0.001) −0.513* (0.269) 0.001 (0.001) 0.001* (0.001) 0.000 (0.001) 0.001* (0.001) 0.001* (0.001) 0.003* (0.002) 0.001** (0.001) 
INDU −0.002 (0.006) −2.860 (2.558) −0.003 (0.006) −0.002 (0.006) −0.018* (0.010) −0.001 (0.006) −0.002 (0.006) 0.052*** (0.018) 0.002 (0.006) 
_cons −1.448*** (0.272) −442.375*** (170.399) −1.641*** (0.267) −1.448*** (0.272) 2.181*** (0.542) −1.551*** (0.276) −1.448*** (0.272) 0.320 (0.664) −1.429*** (0.268) 
Province_FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 
Year_FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 
341 341 341 341 341 341 341 341 341 
Adj_R2 0.983 0.990 0.983 0.983 0.993 0.984 0.983 0.962 0.984 

aSUPPLY (groundwater supply); WSS (Proportion of surface water consumption in total water consumption); IWS (proportion of agricultural and industrial water consumption in total water consumption); PGDP (the natural logarithm of gross regional product per capita); AGRI (the natural logarithm of water consumption per mu of cultivated land under solid irrigation); POP (the natural logarithm of total population); PWC (the natural logarithm of per capita water consumption); uRBAN (Urbanization rate); INDU (the natural logarithm of water consumption per 10,000 yuan of industrial added value).

bThe standard errors adjusted by province-year clustering are in brackets; ***, ** and * indicate significance at the levels of 1, 5 and 10%, respectively.

Heterogeneity analysis: differences in the eastern, central and western regions

The regression results in Table 7 reveal that the influence of water resource tax policy on water poverty in the western region is insignificant compared with those in the eastern and central regions. The impacts on water poverty in the eastern region and central region are positive and significant at the levels of 1 and 5%, respectively. Furthermore, the regression coefficients in Columns (1) and (2) of Table 7 demonstrate that the policy increased the water poverty levels in the experimental group consisting of the eastern and central regions by an average of 1.2 and 1.6%, respectively. The policy effect was clearer. Based on the above empirical test, Hypothesis 3 has been verified.

Table 7

Heterogeneity analysis results: differentiation in Eastern, Central and Western Regions

Independent variableDependent variable: WPI
(1) Eastern(2) Central(3) Western
Treat 0.012***b 0.016** 0.006 
 (0.005) (0.006) (0.005) 
PGDPa 0.132*** 0.204*** −0.006 
 (0.030) (0.063) (0.088) 
AGRI −0.021 −0.065*** −0.016 
 (0.016) (0.023) (0.023) 
POP 0.087* 0.087 0.019 
 (0.044) (0.074) (0.107) 
PWC 0.058** 0.058 0.031 
 (0.025) (0.041) (0.037) 
URBAN 0.000 −0.001 0.001 
 (0.001) (0.002) (0.003) 
INDU 0.010 0.014 −0.016 
 (0.010) (0.011) (0.012) 
Constant −2.166*** −2.576*** 0.022 
 (0.438) (0.549) (0.807) 
Province_FE Yes Yes Yes 
Year_FE Yes Yes Yes 
132 99 110 
R2 0.984 0.960 0.991 
Independent variableDependent variable: WPI
(1) Eastern(2) Central(3) Western
Treat 0.012***b 0.016** 0.006 
 (0.005) (0.006) (0.005) 
PGDPa 0.132*** 0.204*** −0.006 
 (0.030) (0.063) (0.088) 
AGRI −0.021 −0.065*** −0.016 
 (0.016) (0.023) (0.023) 
POP 0.087* 0.087 0.019 
 (0.044) (0.074) (0.107) 
PWC 0.058** 0.058 0.031 
 (0.025) (0.041) (0.037) 
URBAN 0.000 −0.001 0.001 
 (0.001) (0.002) (0.003) 
INDU 0.010 0.014 −0.016 
 (0.010) (0.011) (0.012) 
Constant −2.166*** −2.576*** 0.022 
 (0.438) (0.549) (0.807) 
Province_FE Yes Yes Yes 
Year_FE Yes Yes Yes 
132 99 110 
R2 0.984 0.960 0.991 

aPGDP (the natural logarithm of gross regional product per capita); AGRI (the natural logarithm of water consumption per mu of cultivated land under solid irrigation); POP (the natural logarithm of total population); PWC (the natural logarithm of per capita water consumption); URBAN (urbanization rate); INDU (the natural logarithm of water consumption per 10,000 yuan of industrial added value).

bThe standard errors adjusted by province-year clustering are in brackets; ***, ** and * indicate significance at the levels of 1, 5 and 10%, respectively.

Previous studies have shown that, although the rapid development of China's economy has improved the availability of water resources and the regional distribution of water resources, the continuous increase in water demand and pollution emissions has led to the expansion and local accumulation of China's regional water poverty (Zhou et al. 2020). Therefore, a method of alleviating China's water poverty and realising the sustainable development of water resources is urgently required. The practical experience of foreign water resources tax shows that implementing a water resources tax policy can increase the water-conserving awareness of enterprises and individuals. The policy effectively promotes the rational utilization of water resources, improves water efficiency and protects water resources (Xu 2020). Based on foreign water resource management policies, the Chinese government has formulated and adapted a water resources tax for China.

This research uses a multistage dynamic DID benchmark regression model to test Hypothesis 1. The findings show that the water resource tax policy can effectively reduce water poverty and that the water poverty value of the pilot provinces (municipalities) increases by an average of 0.9 percentage points compared with other non-pilot provinces (municipalities). This conclusion is consistent with the results of similar studies and further proves the thesis that taxing water resources can effectively reduce water poverty (Guo et al. 2019; Yang et al. 2020). The enforcement of a water resources tax can arouse the awareness of water users to conserve water (Agarwal et al. 2000). Additionally, the leverage effect of the water resources tax relatively increases the price of water resources, which leads enterprises and individuals to adjust their habits of using water and to restore the water environment, thus decreasing the occurrence of water poverty (Li et al. 2018).

Hypothesis 2 proposes that the policy of a water resource tax can reduce water poverty by controlling the exploitation of groundwater. Overexploitation of groundwater and pumping cause excessive disturbance of salt stratification in natural groundwater. As a result, groundwater salinization aggravates water poverty (Foster et al. 2013). The research shows that water resource policies reduce the water intake of groundwater and inhibit groundwater exploitation by increasing the tax difference between surface water and groundwater (Ni et al. 2019). Tax differences can foster the replacement of groundwater with more surface water and reduce the pressure of groundwater resources. In addition, the implementation of a water resource tax increases the cost of agricultural water, which is conducive to prompting farmers to abandon flood irrigation and encourage the use of water-conserving irrigation technology such as micro-irrigation and sprinkler irrigation systems (Parween et al. 2021). The waste of agricultural water resources is one of the important reasons for the contradiction between the supply and demand of water resources (Chang et al. 2016). Using water-conserving irrigation technology is conducive to improving agricultural water use efficiency, reducing groundwater intake, promoting sustainable agricultural development and reducing water poverty (Wang et al. 2019).

Moreover, Hypothesis 2 demonstrates that the policy can achieve the goal of reducing water poverty by optimizing the water-use structure. The tax burden increases the cost of enterprise resource development, which forces the transformation and upgrading of these enterprises and promotes the transformation of society to sustainable economic development by encouraging the adjustment of enterprises’ and society's water use structures (Zhang et al. 2020; Ji et al. 2021). Additionally, China has lower utilization efficiency of agricultural and industrial water resources than that in most developed countries (Giordano 2007; Cao et al. 2021). The water resources tax fully uses the tax lever to adjust the water demand and internalizes its tax burden into the operating cost of water users via the price mechanism, which can guide the water-conserving behaviour and avoid the waste of water resources (Tian et al. 2021). Similar studies prove that the implementation of a water resource tax reduces agricultural water use (Zheng & Chen 2021), improves industrial water use efficiency (Zhao & Zhang 2021), and will help to improve China's water use structure. Adjusting the water use structure is conducive to optimally allocating water resources, eliminating the contradiction of water resource utilization, and reducing water poverty (Wei et al. 2018).

Furthermore, this study validates Hypothesis 3 by testing whether the effects of the water resources policy has spatial heterogeneity. The results of spatial heterogeneity analysis show that the policy more significantly impacts the eastern and central regions than the western region. The water poverty value of the eastern provinces (cities) and the central provinces (cities) have increased by an average of 1.2 and 1.6%, respectively. One possible reason is that the central and eastern regions are richer in water resources and concentrated in the industry, and there is great opportunity to reduce industrial wastewater discharge and improve industrial water efficiency (Geng et al. 2014). Moreover, the eastern and central regions are more economically developed, and the location advantage is clearer than that of the western region; therefore, when the tax policy is implemented, these regions become enabled to adopt clean and green water conservation technology, decrease industrial wastewater discharge and promote water resource recycling (Chen et al. 2021). Therefore, the central and eastern regions show more significant effects than the western region in reducing water poverty when applying price leverage.

Based on panel data from 31 provinces (municipalities) in China from 2009 to 2019, this study constructed a multistage dynamic DID model. We explored the ‘net effect’ of the water resources tax policy on reducing water poverty. The WPI was investigated to evaluate water poverty based on five components: access, resources, use, capacity and environment. The effective governance of water poverty depends on price leverage, and we found that the water resources tax policy can mitigate water poverty. The tax policy alleviates water poverty by controlling groundwater exploitation and encouraging water users to improve water-conserving technology to adjust and optimize their water use structures. In addition, due to differences in economic development, geographical location and resource endowment, the water resources tax policy more significantly impacts the suppression of water poverty in the central and eastern regions than in the western region. The results are expected to provide a reference for policy-makers in water poverty management governance and increase the sustainable development of water conservation businesses in areas with water shortages.

This study provides useful information about the relationship between the water resources tax policy and water poverty, which can lead to the following policy implications. First, in the context of ecological civilisation construction, water resource taxes should be highlighted in the tax structure, and the role of taxes in promoting water resource conservation and improving water poverty should be advanced. A water resource tax should be used to efficient input and output of the water resource-based industry and increase the value of the water industry. Second, a water resources tax policy should be implemented accurately and effectively. Due to differences in water resource endowments and economic development in China's provinces (municipalities), the water poverty problems encountered by various regions will differ. Therefore, the implementation of policies should focus on local conditions, and each region should choose the appropriate path that suits local conditions to fully exploit the role of the water tax transaction policy in reducing water poverty.

This work was financially supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (42001221); Shaanxi Provincial Innovation Capability Support Program (2022KRM067); Shaanxi Social Science Fund (2022D049); the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central University (GK202103119); the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central University of Shaanxi Normal University (2022ZYYB25).

All relevant data are included in the paper or its Supplementary Information.

The authors declare there is no conflict.

Agarwal
A.
,
delos Angeles
M. S.
,
Bhatia
R.
,
Chéret
I.
,
Davila-Poblete
S.
,
Falkenmark
M.
,
Villarreal
F. G.
,
Jønch-Clausen
T.
,
Kadi
M. A.
&
Kindler
J.
2000
Integrated Water Resources Management. Global Water Partnership Stockholm
.
Ashenfelter
O.
1978
Estimating the effect of training programs on earnings
.
The Review of Economics and Statistics
60
,
47
57
.
Benyezza
H.
,
Bouhedda
M.
&
Rebouh
S.
2021
Zoning irrigation smart system based on fuzzy control technology and IoT for water and energy saving
.
Journal of Cleaner Production
302
,
127001
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2021.127001
.
Cao
X.
,
Xiao
J.
,
Wu
M.
,
Zeng
W.
&
Huang
X.
2021
Agricultural water use efficiency and driving force assessment to improve regional productivity and effectiveness
.
Water Resources Management
35
(
8
),
2519
2535
.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11269-021-02845-z
.
Chagas
A. L. S.
,
Azzoni
C. R.
&
Almeida
A. N.
2016
A spatial difference-in-differences analysis of the impact of sugarcane production on respiratory diseases
.
Regional Science and Urban Economics
59
,
24
36
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.regsciurbeco.2016.04.002
.
Chang
Y.
,
Li
G.
,
Yao
Y.
,
Zhang
L.
&
Yu
C.
2016
Quantifying the water-energy-food nexus: current status and trends
.
Energies
9
(
2
),
1
17
.
https://doi.org/10.3390/en9020065
.
Chen
X.
,
Hou
B.
,
Zhou
Y.
,
Wang
L.
&
Huang
Y.
2021
A comparative analysis of the spatial and temporal evolution of water use structure in geographical regions of China
.
China Rural Water and Hydropower
6
,
78
90
.
https://doi.org/10.3969/j.issn.1007-2284.2021.06.014
.
Eisenack
K.
,
Edenhofer
O.
&
Kalkuhl
M.
2012
Resource rents: the effects of energy taxes and quantity instruments for climate protection
.
Energy Policy
48
,
159
166
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2012.05.001
.
El-Gafy
I. K. E. D.
2018
The water poverty index as an assistant tool for drawing strategies of the Egyptian water sector
.
Ain Shams Engineering Journal
9
(
2
),
173
186
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.asej.2015.09.008
.
Ergunova
O.
,
Lizunkov
V.
,
Blaginin
V.
,
Politsinskaya
E.
&
Shaykina
O. I.
2018
Formation of the price mechanism for energy resources in Russia and the countries of the European union
.
Materials Testing
8
(
1
),
122
127
.
https://doi.org/10.1515/mt-1999-417-807
.
Fito
J.
&
Van Hulle
S. W. H.
2021
Wastewater reclamation and reuse in agriculture: towards environmental sustainability
.
Environment Development and Sustainability
23
,
2949
2972
.
http://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-020-00732-y
.
Foster
S.
,
Chilton
J.
,
Nijsten
G. J.
&
Richts
A.
2013
Groundwater-a global focus on the ‘local resource’
.
Current Opinion in Environmental Sustainability
5
(
6
),
685
695
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cosust.2013.10.010
.
Gao
P.
&
Yin
C.
2016
Study on establishment of water resource tax system: based on the analysis on practice of water resource fee collection system
.
Journal of Central University of Finance & Economics
1
(
1
),
23
31
.
https://doi.org/CNKI:SUN:ZYCY.0.2016-01-004
.
Geng
Y.
,
Wang
M.
,
Sarkis
J.
,
Xue
B.
,
Zhang
L.
,
Fujita
T.
,
Yu
X.
,
Ren
W.
,
Zhang
L.
&
Dong
H.
2014
Spatial-temporal patterns and driving factors for industrial wastewater emission in China
.
Journal of Cleaner Production
76
,
116
124
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2014.04.047
.
Giordano
M.
2007
Agricultural water policy in China: challenges, issues, and options
.
Water Policy
9
(
SUPPL. 1
),
1
9
.
https://doi.org/10.2166/wp.2007.042
.
Gómez-Llanos
E.
,
Durán-Barroso
P.
&
Robina-Ramírez
R.
2020
Analysis of consumer awareness of sustainable water consumption by the water footprint concept
.
Science of the Total Environment
721
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2020.137743
.
Guo
Y.
,
Jingru
D.
&
Miao
S.
2019
Discussion on the full implementation of water resources tax after the ‘1 + 9’ pilot project
.
Taxation Research
9
,
68
72
.
https://doi.org/10.19376/j.cnki.cn11-1011/f.2019.09.012
.
Heidecke
C.
2006
Development and Evaluation of a Regional Water Poverty Index for Benin
, Vol.
145
.
Intl Food Policy Res Inst
., Washington, DC.
Hotelling
H.
1931
The economics of exhaustible resources
.
Journal of Political Economy
39
(
2
),
137
175
.
https://doi.org/10.1086/254195
.
Hu
J.
,
Zhou
M.
,
Qin
M.
,
Tong
S.
,
Hou
Z.
,
Xu
Y.
,
Zhou
C.
,
Xiao
Y.
,
Yu
M.
&
Huang
B.
2022
Long-term exposure to ambient temperature and mortality risk in China: a nationwide study using the difference-in-differences design
.
Environmental Pollution
292
(
PB
),
118392
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.envpol.2021.118392
.
Ing
J.
2020
Adverse selection, commitment and exhaustible resource taxation
.
Resource and Energy Economics
61
,
101
161
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.reseneeco.2020.101161
.
Jacobs
B.
&
Mooij
R. A. d.
2015
Pigou meets Mirrlees: on the irrelevance of tax distortions for the second-best Pigouvian tax
.
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management
71
,
90
108
.
Jemmali
H.
2017
Mapping water poverty in Africa using the improved multidimensional index of water poverty
.
International Journal of Water Resources Development
33
(
4
),
649
666
.
https://doi.org/10.1080/07900627.2016.1219941
.
Ji
Y.
,
Lei
Y.
,
Li
L.
,
Zhang
A.
,
Wu
S.
&
Li
Q.
2021
Evaluation of the implementation effects and the influencing factors of resource tax in China
.
Resources Policy
72
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resourpol.2021.102126
.
Kilimani
N.
,
van Heerden
J.
&
Bohlmann
H.
2015
Water taxation and the double dividend hypothesis
.
Water Resources and Economics
10
,
68
91
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.wre.2015.03.001
.
Koirala
S.
,
Fang
Y.
,
Dahal
N. M.
,
Zhang
C.
,
Pandey
B.
&
Shrestha
S.
2020
Application of water poverty index (WPI) in spatial analysis of water stress in Koshi River Basin, Nepal
.
Sustainability (Switzerland)
12
(
2
).
https://doi.org/10.3390/su12020727
.
Kosfeld
R.
,
Mitze
T.
,
Rode
J.
&
Wälde
K.
2021
The COVID-19 containment effects of public health measures: a spatial difference-in-differences approach
.
Journal of Regional Science
61
(
4
).
https://doi.org/10.1111/jors.12536
.
Li
P.
,
Qian
H.
&
Wu
J.
2018
Conjunctive use of groundwater and surface water to reduce soil salinization in the Yinchuan Plain, North-West China
.
International Journal of Water Resources Development
34
(
3
),
337
353
.
https://doi.org/10.1080/07900627.2018.1443059
.
Lorphensri
O.
,
Ladawadee
A.
&
Dhammasarn
S.
2011
Review of groundwater management and land subsidence in Bangkok, Thailand
. In:
Groundwater and Subsurface Environments: Human Impacts in Asian Coastal Cities
. pp.
127
142
.
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-53904-9
.
Moser
P.
&
Voena
A.
2012
Compulsory licensing: evidence from the trading with the enemy act
.
American Economic Review
102
(
1
),
396
427
.
Moshtagh
M.
&
Mohsenpour
M.
2020
Community viewpoints about water crisis, conservation and recycling: a case study in Tehran
.
Environment Development and Sustainability.
21
,
2721
2731
.
Ni
J.
,
Wang
F.
&
Tang
G.
2019
Study on experience and comprehensive promotion countermeasures of water resources tax in pilot areas
.
Taxation Research
7
,
33
38
.
https://doi.org/10.19376/j.cnki.cn11-1011/f.2019.07.007
.
Parween
F.
,
Kumari
P.
&
Singh
A.
2021
Irrigation water pricing policies and water resources management
.
Water Policy
23
,
130
141
.
http://doi.org/10.2166/wp.2020.147
.
Prabha
A. S.
,
Ram
A.
&
Irfan
Z. B.
2020
Exploring the relative water scarcity across the Indian million-plus urban agglomerations: an application of the water poverty index
.
HydroResearch
3
,
134
145
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.hydres.2020.10.001
.
Salinas
P.
&
Solé-Ollé
A.
2018
Partial fiscal decentralization reforms and educational outcomes: a difference-in-differences analysis for Spain
.
Journal of Urban Economics
107
,
31
46
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2018.08.003
.
Song
M.
,
Zhu
Q.
,
Peng
J.
&
Santibanez Gonzalez
E. D. R.
2017
Improving the evaluation of cross efficiencies: a method based on Shannon entropy weight
.
Computers and Industrial Engineering
112
,
99
106
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cie.2017.07.023
.
Sullivan
C.
,
Meigh
J.
&
Lawrence
P.
2006
Application of the water poverty index at different scales: a cautionary tale
.
Water International
31
(
3
),
412
426
.
https://doi.org/10.1080/02508060608691942
.
Svensson
J.
,
Wang
Y.
,
Garrick
D.
&
Dai
X.
2021
How does hybrid environmental governance work? Examining water rights trading in China (2000–2019)
.
Journal of Environmental Management
288
,
112333
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2021.112333
.
Thakur
J. K.
,
Neupane
M.
&
Mohanan
A. A.
2017
Water poverty in upper Bagmati River Basin in Nepal
.
Water Science
31
(
1
),
93
108
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.wsj.2016.12.001
.
Thomas
A.
&
Zaporozhets
V.
2017
Bargaining over environmental budgets: a political economy model with application to French water policy
.
Environmental and Resources Economics
68
,
227
248
.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10640-016-0013-7
.
Wang
F.
,
Yu
C.
,
Xiong
L.
&
Chang
Y.
2019
How can agricultural water use efficiency be promoted in China? A spatial-temporal analysis
.
Resources, Conservation and Recycling
145
(
35
),
411
418
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2019.03.017
.
Wang
J.
,
Jiang
Y.
,
Wang
H.
,
Huang
Q.
&
Deng
H.
2020
Groundwater irrigation and management in northern China: status, trends, and challenges
.
International Journal of Water Resources Development
36
(
4
),
670
696
.
https://doi.org/10.1080/07900627.2019.1584094
.
Wei
Y.
,
Wang
Z.
,
Wang
H.
,
Yao
T.
&
Li
Y.
2018
Promoting inclusive water governance and forecasting the structure of water consumption based on compositional data: a case study of Beijing
.
Science of the Total Environment
634
(
2018
),
407
416
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2018.03.325
.
Westmore
B.
2018
Do government transfers reduce poverty in China? Micro evidence from five regions
.
China Economic Review
51
,
59
69
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chieco.2018.05.009
.
Wu
X.
,
Zhang
C.
&
Yang
L.
2021
Evaluation and selection of transportation service provider by Topsis method with entropy weight
.
Thermal Science
25
(
2
),
1483
1488
.
https://doi.org/10.2298/TSCI200301050W
.
Xu
Q.
2020
Water resource tax reform to build resource-saving society
.
Journal of Coastal Research
115
(
sp1
),
506
509
.
https://doi.org/10.2112/JCR-SI115-139.1
.
Yang
D.
,
Zhao
L.
&
Yang
D.
2020
Does water tax improve water efficiency: empirical evidence from Hebei
.
Taxation Research
8
,
48
50
.
https://doi.org/10.19376/j.cnki.cn11-1011/f.2020.08.007
.
Yoon
H.
,
Domene
E.
&
Sauri
D.
2021
Assessing affordability as water poverty in metropolitan Barcelona
.
Local Environment
26
(
11
),
1330
1345
.
https://doi.org/10.1080/13549839.2021.1983790
.
Zhang
Q.
,
Liu
B.
,
Zhang
W.
,
Jin
G.
&
Li
Z.
2015
Assessing the regional spatio-temporal pattern of water stress: a case study in Zhangye City of China
.
Physics and Chemistry of the Earth
79–82
,
20
28
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.pce.2014.10.007
.
Zhang
P.
,
Zou
Z.
,
Liu
G.
,
Feng
C.
,
Liang
S.
&
Xu
M.
2020
Socioeconomic drivers of water use in China during 2002–2017
.
Resources, Conservation and Recycling
154
,
104636
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.resconrec.2019.104636
.
Zheng
G.
&
Chen
L.
2021
Research on the problems and countermeasures of water resources tax reform: based on the pilot reform of ‘1 + 9’ water resource tax
.
Citizen's Weekly
8
(
34
),
89
91
.
https://doi.org/CNKI:SUN:SCZK.0.2021-08-031
.
Zhou
Z. F.
,
Liu
J. H.
,
Zhou
N. X.
,
Zhang
T.
&
Zeng
H. X.
2020
Does the ‘10-point water plan’ reduce the intensity of industrial water pollution? Quasi-experimental evidence from China
.
Journal of Environmental Management.
295
,
113048
.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2021.113048
.
This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution Licence (CC BY-NC-ND 4.0), which permits copying and redistribution for non-commercial purposes with no derivatives, provided the original work is properly cited (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).